by Michael Roberts
The scandal of the Rogoff and Reinhart ‘affair’ (see my post, Revising the two RRs, http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2013/04/17/revising-the-two-rrs/)
rumbles on among mainstream economists. The issue of their ‘mistakes’
and biases has moved onto whether any economic research is being done at
all on a proper scientific basis. As Noah Smith (http://noahpinionblog.blogspot.co.uk/2013/04/the-reason-macroeconomics-doesnt-work.html) pointed out: “While
this particular error is squarely in the lap of Rogoff and Reinhart, I
think it is symptomatic of a broad failure to ensure that empirical
results are replicable, which is the “gold standard by which the
reliability of scientific claims are judged” (National Research Council, 2001). The
lack of replicability of empirical models in economics should be an
embarrassment to a field that has been trying (mistakenly, in my view)
to catch up with the big boys in the natural sciences”. Apparently, even
those journals that have policies requiring submission of data do not
seem to have particularly compelling incentives for authors to actually
cooperate. In this 2007 paper,
Daniel Hamermesh pointed out that the editor of JMCB sought data sets
and documentation from authors with accepted papers in that journal, but
only got about one-third of them.
Smith does not think the two RRs did their research in order to prove austerity was right; no, it was down to useless data. “I don’t think it’s politics
(mostly). I don’t think it’s the culture of consensus and hierarchy. I
don’t think it’s too much math or too little math. I don’t think it’s
the misplaced assumptions of representative agents, flexible prices,
efficient financial markets, rational expectations, etc. Fundamentally,
I think the problem is: uninformative data.”
Noah Smith concludes that “After the financial crisis, a bunch of
people realized how little macroeconomists do know. I think people are
now slowly realizing just how little macroeconomists can know. There is a
difference.”
Well, it’s true that economic analysis often faces difficulty with
its data. There are not many data points to use in judging whether the
Kondratiev economic cycle of 50-60 years exists or not, for example –
something I have been struggling with in my research. But it is not all
as hopeless as Smith reckons. Can we tell if profits lead investment
rather than vice versa? – a bit like the question of causality in the RR
debts: does high debt lead to low growth or vice versa? Well, luckily
for Marxist economic research, we can get somewhere with the question
of profits and investment. My own research in my book, The Great Recession,
provided some proof that profits led investment in the US in analysing
its booms and slumps in the post-war period. But even better work has
been done since by Jose Tapa Granados in his brilliant paper: Does investment cal the tune? (does_investment_call_the_tune_may_2012__forthcoming_rpe_),
where he uses 252 quarterly data points for the Us economy to show a
high correlation between profits and investment and, more important,
statistical significance of the causal direction that profits lead
investment. G Carchedi also has an upcoming piece of research based on
US data with a similar number of data points.
However, Mark Thoma reckoned that what comes out of the R&R debacle is that
“The biggest problem in macroeconomics is the inability of
econometricians of all flavors (classical, Bayesian) to definitively
choose one model over another, i.e. to sort between these imaginative
constructions. We like to think or ourselves as scientists, but if data
can’t settle our theoretical disputes – and it doesn’t appear that it
can – then our claim for scientific validity has little or no merit.
Unfortunately, the time period covered by a typical data set in
macroeconomics is relatively short (so that very few useful policy
experiments are contained in the available data, e.g. there are very few
data points telling us how the economy reacts to fiscal policy in deep
recessions). The point is that for a variety of reasons – the lack of
experimental data, small data sets, and important structural change
foremost among them – empirical macroeconomics is not able to
definitively say which competing model of the economy best explains the
data.
Well, yes, choosing the ‘right model’ or, if you like, the best set
of assumptions (or priors) for a model is very important. If you start
with the Keynesian model assumptions that consumption drives income and
that drives investment, as most DSGE models do (see my post, http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2013/04/03/keynesian-economics-in-the-dsge-trap/),
then, in my view, you are not going to get very far in explaining
capitalist ‘business cycles’ with however much data you have. None of
the DSGE models include profits or profitability as a variable, so they
cannot really explain much. There is a great piece of Marxist research
to do here in ‘modelling’ the ‘business cycle’ with profits as the main
causal variable. Unfortunately, no Marxist economist is ensconced in a
university with a team of students to develop and crunch the numbers.
So we are left where we are. That brings me to what mainstream
economists are thinking right now about the state of the world economy.
They are in total confusion. This week’s batch of global economic
indicators was grim. Business indicators in the key ‘growth’ economies
of the US, China and Germany all slowed sharply, while Europe’s
indicators remain mired in recession mode.
The economic recovery in the advanced economies since 2009 has been
very weak. The IMF published some graphs that show how weak this
recovery has been in the advanced capitalist economies (constituting
about 55-60% of world GDP) compared to previous recoveries from slumps.
In the graphs, the red lines represent the current cycle in the
advanced economies, the blue lines represent the average of three
earlier recessions (1975, 1982 and 1991), and the index numbers are
centred on the year before the recessions started. An abnormally deep
recession in 2008/09 has been followed by an abnormally weak recovery,
so real GDP per capita is now 10 per cent below the levels indicated by
previous cycles (Panel A).
Is the cause of this weak recovery the implementation of the policies
of fiscal austerity,as the Keynesians claim? Gavyn Davies in his FT
blog (http://blogs.ft.com/gavyndavies/2013/04/21/great-recession-and-not-so-great-recovery/) considered the question by looking at these graphs. He concluded that “fiscal
policy has been tightened everywhere to control public debt, which is
much higher than “normal”, so real public spending is about 14 per cent
below the cyclical norm (B). With fiscal policy tightening, the whole
burden of supporting demand has fallen on monetary policy, so nominal
interest rates have fallen to zero (C) and the central banks have
resorted to sizeable increases in their balance sheets (D).”
So stock markets are booming (see my post, http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2013/03/30/its-still-a-bear-market/),
rising on a wave of central bank power money being pumped into the
banks. But companies that are cash-rich are hoarding their money and
don’t invest. The result is that all this ‘wall of money’ goes into
buying shares and bonds and even property. So financial and real estate
markets are booming again and the old cycle of credit-fuelled
unproductive speculation is rearing its very ugly head once again – to
the increasing worry of the IMF and the national monetary authorities.
Would the global recovery have been stronger if fiscal policy had
tightened less rapidly than has actually occurred?
Paul Krugman
certainly thinks so (http://www.nytimes.com/2013/04/22/opinion/krugman-the-jobless-trap.html?_r=1&): “The
main reason our economic recovery has been so weak is that, spooked by
fear-mongering over debt, we’ve been doing exactly what basic
macroeconomics says you shouldn’t do — cutting government spending in
the face of a depressed economy. It’s hard to overstate how
self-destructive this policy is. “ Radical Keynesian and MMT theorist (see my post, http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2012/04/27/effective-demand-liquidity-traps-and-debt-deflation/, Randall Wray is even more adamant: “As I argued in another piece (http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/ppb_111.pdf), in a depressed economy, you need fiscal expansion. “
But Gavyn Davies is not quite so sure that fiscal austerity is the cause of the weak recovery. “Since
the short term fiscal multiplier is almost certainly not zero, the
answer to this question is clearly “yes”, but it is hard to ascribe the
whole of the shortfall in GDP growth to this single factor. If real
government expenditure had performed as normal in this recovery, this
would have resulted in spending being about 5 percentage points of GDP
higher than it is now, so the fiscal multiplier would have needed to be
about 2 in order to explain the whole of the 10 per cent growth
shortfall. This seems implausibly high. Furthermore, monetary policy
would have been tighter in such fiscal circumstances, and there would
have been a somewhat greater (if still small) risk of fiscal crises in
some economies. Therefore the Not-So-Great Recovery is not just a fiscal
story.”
Indeed, despite the exposure of the two RRs, many stick to the view
that the build-up of excessive public sector debt before the Great
Recession that must now be deleveraged is still part of the problem. In
his blog, James Hamilton (http://www.econbrowser.com/archives/2013/04/reinhartrogoff.html) said “The
main reason that I personally am concerned arises from the fact that,
for any level of the interest rate, a higher debt load means that the
government will permanently need to spend more money just to pay the
interest on the debt. In any case (despite the revised data of the two
RRs) you would still conclude that higher debt loads are associated with
slower growth in the postwar advanced economy data set, just as they
were in the postwar emerging economy data set, just as they were in the
centuries-long individual country data sets, and as also was found to be
the case in separate analyses of yet other data sets by Cecchetti, Mohanty and Zampolli (2011), Checherita and Rother (2010), and the IMF (2012), among others.”
Right-wing mainstream economist John Taylor also opposed the idea
that austerity (public sector spending cuts and tax rises) was the cause
of failure to grow whatever the scandal of the two RRs. “The
discovery of errors in the Reinhart-Rogoff paper on the growth-debt
nexus is already impacting policy….offered as a reason why the U.S.
should stop worrying about budget reform and consolidation and start
worrying about austerity. But the claims about austerity in the
current budget proposals are exaggerated. Consider the recent House
budget proposal which balances the budget in 10 years without raising
taxes by gradually reducing the growth of spending. It would reduce
federal outlays as a share of GDP by 3.1 percentage points over the next
decade (from 22.2% in 2013 to 19.1% in 2023). Critics label it
austere, but this is less spending restraint than the 4.1 percentage
point reduction in outlays as a share of during the 1990s (when spending
fell from 22.3% in 1991 to 18.2 % in 2000). With this spending
restraint, the 1990s were a very good decade for economic stability and
growth, and they left the budget in balance. The same can be said for
the next decade. The benefits of properly addressing the debt and
deficit problems are enormous and the costs are surprising small.”
So austerity is not causing a problem because there isn’t any, but if
you do it, it will help in the long term! Taylor’s argument is
weakened when you realise that the reason that spending as a share of
GDP fell in the 1990s was because real GDP growth was much stronger
than post-2009. If the US economy had been growing at the 1990s
average, then the fall in government spending as a share of GDP now
would be much greater and quicker – and austerity would look very
severe. So is it austerity that enables growth or growth that enables
austerity? Here we go again.
Gavyn Davies goes on to blame the banking system and the failure to
boost credit as the cause of weakness. I don’t see how this follows.
There has been a huge expansion of credit. This has ended up in the
banking system, to be used to buy financial assets and start a
speculative boom. Money has not got through to the real economy not
mainly because the banks are crippled in their ability to lend but
mainly because there is no demand to borrow from overleveraged small
businesses and cash-rich large businesses – you can’t make a horse drink
(see my post, http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2013/03/04/you-cant-make-a-horse-drink-2/).
If central bank largesse is merely fuelling another financial bubble
and not real GDP growth or even inflation, then another crisis could be
on its way. That’s the worry of some mainstream economists. The last
credit bubble from 2002-7 apparently was deliberately started or allowed
to happen as the only way to get the modern capitalist economy going.
According to Transcripts of the Fed’s internal meetings March 16, 2004,
Donald Kohn, a longtime Fed staffer who later became the Fed’s vice
chairman, said that the credit bubble was “deliberate and a desirable effect of the stance of policy.” According to Kohn, the Fed’s strategy was to: “boost asset prices in order to stimulate demand.”
Indeed, in a recent speech, Nayarana Kocherlakota, the president of the Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank, reckons that the Fed
“will only be able to achieve its congressionally mandated objectives
by following policies that result in signs of financial market
instability.” So the Fed is incapable of lowering the
unemployment rate without creating more bubbles. Kocherlakota said that
the Fed needed real interest rates to be “unusually low for a considerable period of time” and that this would lead to “unusual financial market outcomes” including “inflated asset prices, high asset return volatility and heightened merger activity.” John Taylor commented that surely there must be a better way.
Well yes, there is. What caused the Great Recession was a collapse
in capitalist investment, not excessive public sector debt, and what is
causing the slow recovery is the lack of renewed investment. Look at
these graphics from John Ross’ blog (http://ablog.typepad.com/keytrendsinglobalisation/2013/04/investments-failure-to-recover.html).
In constant price dollar PPPs, the form in which the OECD publishes
the statistics, OECD GDP in the 4th quarter of 2012, the latest
available data, was $625bn above its level in the 1st quarter of 2008.
Government expenditure was $326bn above its 4th quarter 2008 level, net
exports $482bn above, and personal consumption $659bn above. However
fixed investment was $700bn below its 4th quarter 2008 level. It is
therefore clearly the depression of fixed investment that remains the
key weakness in the advanced economies.
The trend can also be seen clearly in the quarterly percentage change
in the domestic components of GDP in each quarter between the 1st
quarter of 2008 and the 4th quarter of 2012. Personal consumption
continues to recover – being 2.8% above its 1st quarter 2008 level.
Government consumption is 5.0% above its 1st quarter 2008 level –
although this has essentially remained static since 2010, and is now
mildly falling, reflecting various austerity policies. The key problem
is that fixed investment remains –8.8% down.
This is not to deny that austerity has not played a role in the weak
recovery. The great supporter of austerity, the UK government, has just
announced that it scraped through in meeting its borrowing target for
the fiscal year 2012-013. But it only did so by slashing public sector
investment spending at a time when private sector investment is still at
lows. As Jonathan Portes explained in his blog: “most
of the deficit reduction has come from cutting public sector net
investment (spending on schools, roads, hospitals, etc) roughly in half.
Pretty much all the rest came from tax increases (note that the
investment cuts and tax increases were both, to a significant extent,
policies inherited from the previous government). And we can see when it
happened – between 2009-10 and 2011-12. But
these sources of deficit reduction stopped in 2011-12, because the
government belatedly realised that cutting investment was a major
mistake and that the economic imperative was actually to do precisely
the opposite (not that there was much investment left to cut); and it
stopped putting up taxes overall. So we can see also what’s happened
since – with the impact of the weak economy on tax receipts reducing
revenues, the deficit has been flat and is projected to stay flat.” Austerity was not working and has now been abandoned.
But why did investment collapse in the first place? That would help
us look at how it might be revived. I have argued many times on this
blog that there are two reasons. The first is that profitability in the
main capitalist economies dropped after 2006 , heralding the Great
Recession of 2008-9. And the rate of profit in most economies has not
recovered to pre-crisis levels (in the US it has – just). So there is
no ability or desire to raise investment.
The second reason was the huge build-up of private sector debt before the crisis (see my post http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2013/02/25/deleveraging-and-profitability-again/).
So we are not talking about the Reinhart and Rogoff story of public
sector debt, but at the private sector. This overhang of ‘fictitious
capital’ still restricts the ability or willingness of households to
spend as they pay down debt or default on their mortgages and for
companies (not just banks) to invest when their returns only just cover
the servicing of their debts (zombie operations). Only low interest
rates have kept many firms in business, even in the US (graph).
Pumping money into the financial sector is not working to restore
sufficient investment growth to get unemployment down and households to
spend. Although fiscal austerity has played a role in delaying the
recovery of investment, the real cause lies in the capitalist sector
itself (see my post,http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2013/02/10/why-is-there-a-long-depression/).
In that sense, the scandal of the two RRs does not provide sufficient
ammunition for Keynesians to suggest that more government spending will
cure the economy, get growth up and public debt down. If the lack of
investment is the problem, what is needed is for a plan of public
investment for jobs, the environment and in technology that does not
depend on raising the profitability of the corporate sector, indeed,
aims on replacing it.
If you have opinions about the subject matter of posts on this blog please share them. Do you have a story about how the system affects you at work school or home, or just in general? This is a place to share it.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment