by Michael Roberts
There has been an eruption of an old debate among mainstream economics bloggers.
The debate is about, first, whether there is a ‘natural rate of
interest’ that provides equality between investment and savings in an
economy at full employment; and second, whether current interest rates
in the major economies are above or below that ‘natural’ rate.
The concept of a ‘natural’ rate where desired investment in new
structures, equipment and technology matches desired saving by
households and firms in a ‘general equilibrium’ comes from the
neoclassical economist of the late 19th century Knut Wicksell.
He argued that if investment exceeded savings in an economy, the
natural rate would rise so that savings would then increase to match
investment and vice versa. If for some reason, the natural rate did not
rise, then there would ‘overheating’ in the economy, in the form of
inflation. In the recession example, savings would be greater than
investment and if the natural rate did not fall enough to reduce the
desire to save, then there would be less than full employment.
Now you can see why this concept of a ‘natural rate’ might be
important. Maybe current market rates are too high compared to the
natural rate so that we have a glut of saving (hoarding of money) and
not enough investment – stagnation. But maybe market rates are too low,
below the natural rate, so that we have inflation being expressed in a
bubble in property and financial assets. This is the nature of the
argument between the conservative neo-classical (Austrians) and the
Keynesians.
As leading Keynesian Brad Delong put it: “Bill White, formerly of the Bank for International Settlements, has argued
the Wicksellian natural rate must be high and monetary policy too loose
because low rates have encouraged all sorts of yield-chasing behavior.
But [W]e don’t see businesses dipping into their cash reserves to fund
investment; a monetary hot potato; unexpected and rising inflation; and
full or over-full employment. Instead, we see elevated unemployment and
firms and households adding to their cash reserves. This is what
Wicksell expected to see when the natural rate of interest was below the
market rate: planned investment would then be lower than desired
savings, households and businesses seeking to save would then transfer
some of their cash out of transactions balances and treat them as
unspendable savings (the “precautionary” or “speculative” demand for
money), we would see too little money to buy all the goods and services
that would be put on sale at full employment, and we would see no signs
of inflation but a depressed economy. That is the root of our problem:
the natural nominal rate of interest … today is less than zero, and so
the Federal Reserve cannot push the market nominal rate of interest down
low enough.”
But is there a natural rate of interest? Does this concept help us
understand what is happening in an economy, especially in the major
capitalist economies right now? Well, Keynes dismissed the idea arguing that there was not one static natural rate but a series of rates depending on the level of investment,
consumption and saving in an economy and the desire to hoard money
(liquidity preference). And there was no reason to assume that the
capitalist economy would ‘correct’ any mismatch between investment and
savings, particularly in a depression, by market interest rates
adjusting back to the ‘natural rate’ in some automatic market process.
That’s because in a depression where investment returns are too low
compared to the money rate of interest, capitalists will hoard their
money rather than invest in a ‘liquidity trap’.
Marx too denied the concept of a natural rate of interest.
For him, the return on capital, whether exhibited in the interest
earned on lending money, or dividends from holding shares, or rents from
owning property, came from the surplus-value appropriated from the
labour of the working class and appropriated by the productive sectors
of capital. Interest was a part of that surplus value. The rate of
interest would thus fluctuate between zero and the average rate of
profit from capitalist production in an economy. In boom times, it
would move towards the average rate of profit and in slumps it would
fall towards zero. But the decisive driver of investment would be
profitability, not the interest rate. If profitability was low, then
holders of money would increasingly hoard money or speculate in
financial assets rather than invest in productive ones. What matters is
not whether the market rate of interest is above or below some
‘natural’ rate but whether it is so high that it is squeezing any profit
for investment in productive assets.
Both Keynes and Marx looked not to a concept of a natural rate of
interest’ but to the relation of interest rate for holding money to the
profitability (or return) on productive capital. Actually, so did
Wicksell. According to Wicksell, the natural rate is “never high or
low in itself, but only in relation to the profit which people can make
with the money in their hands, and this, of course, varies. In good
times, when trade is brisk, the rate of profit is high, and, what is of
great consequence, is generally expected to remain high; in periods of
depression it is low, and expected to remain low.”
More recently, the architect of modern ‘unconventional monetary
policy as the solution to the ills of modern capitalism, Ben Bernanke,
former chief of the US Fed, agreed. Bernanke tells us that low interest
rates are here to stay, but not because of lax monetary policy, but because the real rate of return on assets (both tangible and financial) are staying low.
They are low not because the Fed and other central banks have pumped
too much money into the economy – although that used to be what Ben said
he wanted to do. No, the reason for low interest rates is the low rate
of return on capital investment. “The real interest rate is most
relevant for capital investment decisions, for example. The Fed’s
ability to affect real rates of return, especially longer-term real
rates, is transitory and limited. Except in the short run, real interest
rates are determined by a wide range of economic factors, including
prospects for economic growth—not by the Fed.”
Turning to Wicksell, Bernanke says the problem is that the equilibrium real rate is low because “investment opportunities are limited and relatively unprofitable.”… What
this tells you is that monetary policy is restricted in its impact by
what is going on in the ‘real’ economy, more specifically, the dominant
capitalist sector. “The bottom line is that the state of
the economy, not the Fed, ultimately determines the real rate of return
attainable by savers and investors.”
Ben’s argument that it is the underlying real rate of return on
investment that decides things, not Federal Reserve monetary policy, is
really to justify and defend his actions as Fed chair against criticism
from the Austrian school and the neoliberal camp that he kept interest
rates artificially too low; and from Keynesian camp that he did not
intervene enough. You see, the critics are wrong about Fed policy
because the Fed has little say in the underlying growth or otherwise of
the US capitalist economy. That depends on its underlying
profitability, or in Wicksell’s language, the ‘equilibrium ‘natural rate
of return’. “The state of the economy, not the Fed, is the ultimate
determinant of the sustainable level of real returns. This helps
explain why real interest rates are low throughout the industrialized
world, not just in the United States.”
Of course, there is no discussion of why profitability (or the
natural rate of return) is low. Modern mainstream monetary theory has
actually forgotten the points made by Wicksell, let alone Keynes or
Marx. The modern proponents actually seem to believe in some natural
rate of interest and reckon that boosting the money supply or lowering
interest rates to zero (or even negative) will boost consumption and
investment. The barrier of low profitability is ignored.
Previous Fed chair, Alan Greenspan actually reckoned that interest
rates should be fixed so that speculation in financial assets could be
encouraged and this would boost productive investment and consumption.
Well, his policy led to a credit-fuelled property and stock market boom and bust. Top monetary economist, Michael Woodford also reckoned that Fed monetary policy could be manipulated so that it increased inflation expectations among households leading them to spend more.
And now the current Fed chair Janet Yellen has gone even further. She backs Fed
economic research that suggests very low interest rates could inspire
increased consumption and investment so that demand creates its own
supply. This is the mirror opposite of Say’s law, rebutted by both
Marx and Keynes, that supply can create its own demand. So keep
interest rates slow or at zero. But the evidence for this extreme
monetarist Keynesianism is poor. And ironically, Yellen is set to hike
Fed rates in December.
Both propositions (supply creates demand or demand creates supply)
suggest that the capitalist economy can ‘correct’ itself through market
processes, either because saving will lead directly to investment (Say)
or investment can match saving through fixing interest rates at the
‘natural rate of interest’ (Wicksell). Neither proposition makes sense
or works in an economy where investment is set by profitability. If
the return on productive capital is too low, what happens to the rate of
interest or savings will change nothing.
No comments:
Post a Comment