by Michael Roberts
Was it necessary for America to go to war in order to establish a sustained recovery in its capitalist economy or did the New Deal and Keynesian-type policies of easy money (low interest rates) and fiscal stimulus (tax cuts and government spending) do the trick well before the
war economy became dominant?
It is a key argument of Marxist economics (at least in my version!)
that capitalist economies can only recover in a sustained way if average
profitability for the productive sectors of the economy rises
significantly. And that would require the sufficient destruction in the
value of ‘dead capital’ (past accumulation) that is no longer
profitable to employ.
From that flows the argument that the Great Depression of the 1930s
in the US economy lasted so long because profitability did not recover
throughout that decade. I checked the data from the US Bureau of
Economic Analysis for the period. To get the rate of profit, I measured
corporate profits against net fixed assets in the corporate sector,
valued on a historic cost basis. The evidence is clear (see graph): in
1938, the US corporate rate of profit was still less than half the rate
of 1929.
It was the same story for the mass of corporate profits too. Even by 1940, profits were still below that of 1929.
Indeed, it is clear from these graphs that profitability only picked up once the war economy was under way, by 1940 onwards.
But maybe profitability in the capitalist sector is irrelevant to
economic recovery and what matters is monetary and fiscal stimulation of
effective demand (i.e investment and consumption). That would be the
Keynesian explanation of the depression: namely that there was a
‘liquidity trap’ that had to be released by ‘easy money’ policies and
fiscal spending to stimulate the private sector; a ‘magneto problem’, as
Keynes called it. Arch-Keynesian economists Brad de Long and Larry
Summers wrote a piece way back in 1998 entitled Does macroeconomic policy affect output?, Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity (1988:2), pp. 433-80. In their paper, they
argued that US economic recovery was already well under way by 1942
when the US entered the world war. De Long and Summers calculated that
more than five-sixths of the decline in output relative to trend that
occurred during the Depression had been made up before 1942. They found
it “hard to attribute any of the pre-1942 catch-up to the war.” So the Marxist account that it was war that transformed US capitalism and got it out of the Great Depression is wrong.
However, their estimates have been contested by Professor John
Vernon. Vernon agreed that the US economy completed its recovery from
the Great Depression in 1942, restoring full-employment output in that
year after 12 years of below-full employment performance. However,
Keynesian-type fiscal policies were not the most important factor from
1933 through 1940. Only after that did they become the most important
factor, when the recovery was less than half-complete. So it was World
War II fiscal policies that were instrumental in the overall restoration
of full-employment performance (see Vernon’s World War II Fiscal Policies and the End of the Great Depression, Journal of Economic History, 1994).
Vernon shows that more than 80% of the 1941 increase in real GNP can be
attributed to World War II-associated federal fiscal policies. “Thus
World War II fiscal policies did much more than simply complete a
recovery already largely accomplished: they were, for more than half the
recovery, the major determinant in the restoration of full-employment
performance.”
If US economic recovery from the Great Depression did not start until
the world war was well under way, then it lends support to the view
that Keynesian-type monetary or fiscal policy won’t work and the Marxist
view that capital values must be destroyed to restore profitability to
get capitalist economic recovery. And remember, the destruction of
capital values means the bankruptcy of many companies, a huge rise in
unemployment and even the physical destruction of things and people in
their millions.
I had a new look at the evidence starting with GDP, the main
indicator used by De Long and Summers. By 1938, the level of US real
GDP was still below the level of 1929. There was no significant rise in
US real GDP until 1940, after which GDP really took off to reach double
the 1929 level by 1944.
And if we look at the key Keynesian categories of consumption and
investment, we find that US investment levels again did not take off
until 1941 and, most interestingly, consumption continued to fall,
dramatically once the war began.
So there is no evidence of recovery before the war ‘kicked in’.
Investment took off from 1941 onwards to reach, as a share of GDP, way
more than double the level that investment stood at in 1940. Why was
that? Well, it was not the result of a pick-up in private sector
investment. What happened was a massive rise in government investment
and spending. In 1940, private sector investment was still below the
level of 1929 and actually fell further during the war. The state
sector took over nearly all investment, as resources (value) were
diverted to the production of arms and other security measures in a war
economy.
But is not increased government investment and consumption a form of
Keynesian stimulus, but just at a higher level? Well, no. The
difference is revealed in the continued collapse of consumption. The
war economy was paid for by restricting the opportunities for workers to
spend their incomes from their war-time jobs. There was forced saving
through the purchase of war bonds, rationing and increased taxation to
pay for the war. Government investment meant the direction and planning
of production by government decree. The war economy did not stimulate
the private sector, it replaced the ‘free market’ and capitalist
investment for profit. Consumption did not restore economic growth as
Keynesians (and those who see the cause of crisis in under-consumption)
should expect; instead it was investment in mainly weapons of mass
destruction.
The war decisively ended the depression. American industry was
revitalized by the war and many sectors were oriented to defence
production (for example, aerospace and electronics) or completely
dependent on it (atomic energy). The war’s rapid scientific and
technological changes continued and intensified trends begun during the
Great Depression. As the war severely damaged every major economy in the
world except for the US, American capitalism gained economic and
political hegemony after 1945.
In many industries, company executives resisted converting to
military production because they did not want to lose consumer market
share to competitors who did not convert. Conversion thus became a goal
pursued by public officials and labor leaders. Auto companies only fully
converted to war production in 1942 and only began substantially
contributing to aircraft production in 1943. Pearl Harbor was an
enormous spur to conversion. From the beginning of preparedness in 1939
through the peak of war production in 1944, the war economy could not
be left to the capitalist sector to deliver. To organize the war
economy and to ensure that it produced the goods needed for war, the
federal government spawned an array of mobilization agencies which not
only often purchased goods but closely directed those goods’ manufacture
and heavily influenced the operation of private companies and whole
industries.
The military services were largely able to curtail production
destined for civilians (e.g., automobiles or many non-essential foods)
and even for war-related but non-military purposes (e.g., textiles and
clothing). And the Department of the Treasury introduced the first
general income tax in American history and “war bonds” sold to the
public. Beginning in 1940, the government extended the income tax to
virtually all Americans and collected it by deductions from wages at
source. Those subject to income tax rose from 4 million in 1939 to 43
million in 1945!
With such a large pool of taxpayers, the American government took in
$45 billion in 1945, an enormous increase over the $8.7 billion
collected in 1941, although still far short of the $83 billion spent on
the war in 1945. Over that same period, federal tax revenue grew from
about 8 percent of GDP to more than 20 percent. All told, taxes
provided about $136.8 billion of the war’s total cost of $304 billion.
To cover the other $167.2 billion, the Treasury Department also expanded
its bond program, which served as a valuable source of revenue for the
federal government. By the time war-bond sales ended in 1946, 85m
Americans had purchased more than $185 billion worth of the securities,
often through automatic deductions from their paychecks.
The Office of Price Administration attempted to curtail inflation by
maintaining prices at their March 1942 levels. And the National War
Labor Board limited wartime wage increases to about 15%. Although wages
rose about 65% over the course of the war, the national living standard
barely stayed level or even declined. About 10.5 million Americans who
either could not then have had jobs (the 3.25 million youths who came
of age after Pearl Harbor) or who would not have then sought employment
(3.5 million women, for instance). Almost 19 million American women
(including millions of black women) were working outside the home by
1945. Labour mobility was huge. About 15 million civilian Americans
moved. Migration was especially strong along rural-urban axes,
especially to war-production centers around the country, permanently
altering their demographics and economies.
As Guiglelmo Carchedi summed it in a recent piece (Behind and beyond the crisis, International Socialism, no 132, October 2011 http://isj.org.uk/index.php4?id=761&issue=132): “Why
did the war bring about such a jump in profitability in the 1940‐5
period? The denominator of the rate not only did not rise, but dropped
because the physical depreciation of the means of production was greater
than new investments. At the same time, unemployment practically
disappeared. Decreasing unemployment made higher wages possible. But
higher wages did not dent profitability. In fact, the conversion of
civilian into military industries reduced the supply of civilian goods.
Higher wages and the limited production of consumer goods meant that
labour’s purchasing power had to be greatly compressed in order to avoid
inflation. This was achieved by instituting the first general income
tax, discouraging consumer spending (consumer credit was prohibited) and
stimulating consumer saving, principally through investment in war
bonds. Consequently, labour was forced to postpone the expenditure of a
sizeable portion of wages. At the same time labour’s rate of
exploitation increased. In essence, the war effort was a
labour‐financed massive production of means of destruction.”
I am not suggesting from this that the current Long Depression will
only end with a new world war at the expense of millions of lives and
destruction of material wealth. But what the story of the Great
Depression and the war shows is that, once capitalism is in the depth of
a long depression, there must be a grinding and deep destruction of all
that capitalism had accumulated in previous decades before a new era of
expansion becomes possible. There is no policy that can avoid that and preserve the capitalist sector.
Let Keynes sum it up “It is, it seems, politically impossible for
a capitalistic democracy to organize expenditure on the scale necessary
to make the grand experiments which would prove my case — except in war
conditions,” from The New Republic (quoted from P. Renshaw, Journal of Contemporary History 1999 vol. 34 (3) p. 377 -364).
No comments:
Post a Comment