by Michal Roberts
In my first post on Modern Monetary Theory (MMT),
I offered a general analysis of the theory, its similarities and
differences with Marx’s theory of money; and some of the policy
implications of the MMT and its usefulness for the labour movement.
In this post, I want to delve deeper into the analytics of MMT. As I
said in the first post, MMT is the child of what is called Chartalism,
namely that money is historically the creation of the state and not, as
mainstream neoclassical theory claims, an extension from barter trading;
or in the Marxist view that money appears with the emergence of markets
and commodity production (“Money necessarily crystallises out of
the process of exchange, in which different products of labour are in
fact equate with each other, and thus converted into commodities…. as
the transformation of the products of labour into commodities is
accomplished, one particular commodity is transformed into money.” – Marx Capital Vol 1).
I won’t tackle whether Chartalism is an accurate historical account
of the emergence of money. Instead, let me refer you to an excellent
short account of the history of money by Argentine Marxist economist,
Rolando Astarita, here.
Astarita has also analysed MMT in several posts on his blog, and I
shall draw on some of his arguments. Suffice it to say that to argue
that money only arose because the role of the state in pre-capitalist
economies is not borne out by the facts.
Nevertheless, MMT starts with the conviction that it is the state
(not capitalist commodity relations) that establishes the value of
money. Leading MMTer Randall Wray argues the money takes its value not
from merchandise “but rather from the will of the State to accept it for payment”. Chartalist founder Knapp says: “money is a creature of the law”; “The denomination of means of payment according to the new units of value is a free act of the authority of the State”; and “in modern monetary systems the proclamation [by the State] is always supreme”. Thus the modern monetary system “is an administrative phenomenon” and nothing more.
Keynes also backed this Chartalist view. In his Treatise on Money, Keynes says: “the
Chartalist or state money was reached when the State assumed the right
to declare which account money is to be considered money at a given
moment”. So “the money of account, especially that in which
debts, prices and general purchasing power are expressed, is the basic
concept of the theory of money”. I don’t think it is
correct to say that MMT bastardises Keynes (as one comment on my first
post argues) – on the contrary, MMT and Keynes are in agreement that
money is a product of state creation as the state decides the unit of account for all transactions.
But deciding the unit of account (eg whether dollars or euros) is not the same as deciding its value
for transactions ie as a measure or store of value. MMT supposedly
supports the ‘endogenous’ money approach, namely that money is created
by the decisions of entrepreneurs to invest or households to spend, and
from the loans that the banks grant them for that purpose. So banks make
loans and so create money (as issued by the state). Money is deposited
by the receivers of loans and then they pay taxes back to the state.
According MMT, loans are created by banks and then deposits are
destroyed by taxation, in that order. At a simple level, MMT merely
describes the way things work with banking and money – and this is what
many MMTers argue: ‘all we are doing is saying like it is’.
But MMT goes further. It argues that the state creates money in
order to receive it for the payment of taxes. The state can force taxes
out of citizens and can decide the nature of the legal tender that
serves for money. So money is a product of the state. Thus MMT has a
circuit of money that goes: state money – others (non-state entities) –
taxes – state money. The state injects money into the private sector,
and that money is then reabsorbed with the collection of taxes.
According to MMT, contrary to what most of us simpletons think, issuing
money and collecting taxes are not alternatives, but actions that merely
occur at different times of the same circuit. So if a government runs a
fiscal deficit and spends more than it receives in taxes, the non-state
sector has a surplus which it can use to invest, spend and employ more.
The state deficit can thus be financed by creating more money. Taxes
are not needed to finance state spending, but to generate demand for
money (to pay taxes!).
But the MMT circuit fails to show what happens with the money that
capitalists and households have. In MMT, M (in value) can be increased
to M’ purely by state dictat. For Marx, M can only be
increased to M’ if capitalist production takes place to increase value
in commodities that are sold for more money. This stage is ignored by
MMT. The MTT circuit starts from the state to the non-state sectors and
back to the state. But this is the wrong way round, causally. The
capitalist circuit starts with the money capitalist and through
accumulation and exploitation of labour back to the money capitalist,
who then pays the state in taxes etc. MMT ignores this. But it shows
that money is not exogenous to capitalist economic activity. Its value
is not controlled by the state.
MMT creates the illusion that this whole process starts and ends with
the government when it really starts within the capitalist sector
including the banking system. Taxes cannot destroy money because taxes
logically occur after some level of spending on private output occurs.
Taxes are incurred when the private sector spends and governments decide
to use those taxes to mobilize some resources for the state. Private
incomes and spending on resources precede taxes.
Another Chartalist, Tcherneva writes: “Chartalists
argue that, since money is a public monopoly, the government has at its
disposal a direct way to determine its value. Remember that for Knapp
the payments with currency measure a certain number of units of value.
For example, if the State required that in order to obtain a
high-powered money unit a person must provide one hour of work, then the
money would be worth exactly one hour of work. As a monopoly issuer of
the currency, the State can determine what the currency will be worth by
establishing the terms in which the high-powered money is obtained“(page 18). Tcherneva’s policy of State ‘exogenous pricing’ is pretty similar to the views of 19th century utopian socialist John Gray who reckoned that by issuing bonds that were exogenously priced to represent working time, so economies could deliver growth and full employment – a view that Marx criticised.
Where MMT differs from Keynesian-type fiscal deficit spending is that its proponents see government deficits as permanent
in order to drive the economy up and achieve full employment of
resources. In this way, the state becomes the “employer of last
resort”. Indeed, the MMT exponents claim that unemployment can indeed
be solved within capitalism. So there is no need to change the social
formations based on private capital. All that is needed is for
politicians and economists to recognise that state spending ‘financed’
by money creation can sustain full employment.
MMT proponent Tcherneva writes: “Chartalists propose a policy of
full employment in which the state exogenously establishes an important
price for the economy, which in turn serves as an anchor for all other
prices …. This proposal is based on the recognition that the State does
not face operational financial constraints, that unemployment is a
result of restricting the issuance of currency, and that the State can
exercise an exogenous pricing (exogenous pricing)” This policy
conclusion is rather ironic. It leads to a view that full employment can
be achieved by the “exogenous” issuance of currency at a fixed price.
And yet MMT is prominent in its rejection of the monetarist argument
that an exogenous increase in the quantity of money will lead to a boost
in economic activity. It seems that MMT also has an exogenous theory of
money!
As Cullen Roche, an orthodox Keynesian, put it: “MMT
tries to reinvent the wheel and argue that it is the government’s fault
(and implicitly, the rest of society’s fault) that you can’t find a
job… MMT gets the causality backwards here by starting with the state
and working out.” Roche goes on: “The proper causality is that
private resources necessarily precede taxes. Without a highly productive
revenue generating private sector there is nothing special about the
assets created by a government and it is literally impossible for these
assets to remain valuable. We create equity when we produce real goods
and services or increase the market value of our assets relative to
their liabilities via productive output. It is completely illogical and
beyond silly to argue that one can just “print” equity from thin air.
Government debt is, logically, a liability of the society that creates
it. In the aggregate government debt is a liability that must be
financed by the productive output of that society.”
One comment on my first post queried my claim that MMT exponents
reckon that money can be created out of thin air – this was a distortion
of MMT, I was told. The real argument of MMT is that government
spending can finance itself by raising economic activity and thus more
taxes. I did cite some economists who talked about ‘thin air’ but
apparently these were not true MMTers. Well, British tax
expert/economist, Richard Murphy, is definitely a supporter of MMT. He
expounded that MMT first says “governments can make money
out of thin air, at will… MMT then says all government spending is in
fact funded by money created in this way, created by central banks on
the government’s behalf… MMT logically argues as a consequence that
there is no such thing as tax and spend when considering the activity of
the government in the economy; there can only be spend and tax.” Similarly, Stephanie Kelton
is currently the most followed MMT economist. She argues that
governments can expand spending to whatever level necessary to achieve
full use of productive resources in an economy by state money because
such spending is ‘self-financing’.
Money only has value because if there is value in production to back
it. Government spending cannot create that value – indeed some
government spending can destroy value (armaments etc). Productive value
is what gives money credibility. A productive private sector generates
the domestic product and income that gives government liabilities
credibility in the first place. When that credibility is not there,
then trust in the state’s currency can disappear fast, as we see in
Venezuela or Zimbabwe, and even Turkey right now (I’ll come back to this
in a future post).
To quote Cullen Roche again: “productive output MUST, by
necessity, precede taxes. In this sense it is proper to say that
productive output drives money. And if productive output collapses then
there is no quantity of men with guns that can force people to pay
taxes… So the important point here is that a government is
indeed constrained in its spending. It is constrained by the quantity
and quality of its private sector’s productive output. And the quantity
and quality of income that the private sector can create is the amount
of income that constrains the government’s ability to spend.” This
is Keynesian terminology: but if we alter the word ‘income’ or ‘output’
to ‘value’, we can get the point in Marxist terms.
Marx’s theory of money concurs with the endogenous approach in so far
that it is the capitalist sector that creates the demand for money; to
act a means of exchange and a store of value. Banks make loans and
create deposits, not vice versa. Indeed, Marx’s theory of money is more
consistently endogenous than MMT because it recognises the
primacy of the capitalist accumulation process (with banks and markets)
in deciding the value of money, not any ‘exogenous’ role of the
state. As Astarita puts it: “the fundamental difference between the
Marxist approach to money and the Chartalist approach revolves around
this single point. In Marx’s conception, money can only be understood as
a social relation. In the Chartalist approach, it is an artifice in
which essential social determinations are missing…..it “sweeps under the
carpet” the centrality of productive work, and the exploitation of
work, the true basis on which capitalist society is based.”
The state cannot establish at will the value of the money that is
issued for the very simple reason is that, in a capitalist economy, it
is not dominant and all-powerful. Capitalist companies, banks and
institutions rule and they make decisions on the basis of profit and
profitability. As a result, they endogenously drive the value of
commodities and money. Marx’s law of value says value is anchored
around the socially necessary labour time involved in the overall
production of commodities (goods and services), ie by the average
productivity of labour, the technologies and intensity of work. The
state cannot overcome or ignore this reality.
And it is reality. Let me offer some simple empirical evidence
(something MMTers do not do). Government spending in modern economies,
particularly the ones that dominate MMT thinking (they don’t have much
to say on so-called emerging economies – but I’ll come back to that in
the next post), like the US or the UK or the G7, is around 30-50% of
GDP. Government investment is only about 3-5% of GDP. This compares
with capitalist sector investment of 15-25%, while household spending
varies between 55-70% of GDP. The quantity of domestically held
government bonds in the US is just 4% of private sector net worth.
I did a small empirical analysis of the relation between government
expenditure and unemployment. According to MMT, you would expect that
the higher the ratio of government spending in an economy, the lower the
unemployment. Well, the evidence shows the opposite! Government
spending in France is over 55% of GDP, while it is 39% in Japan and 38%
in the US. But which of these three countries has the higher
unemployment rate? France 9%; Japan 2.4% and the US 4%. Most advanced
capitalist economies with higher government spending ratios had higher
unemployment rates. This shows that there are other reasons than the
lack of state spending for the level of unemployment in capitalist
economies.
So state issuance is hardly a key driving force of the economy and
employment. Of course, MMT exponents sometimes argue that this is the
problem – just expand government spending, particularly investment, fund
it by ‘issuing money’ and then the state will exogenously
overcome or bypass failing capitalist accumulation. But this response
immediately begs the question, studiously ignored by MMT, that it is the
capitalist sector that runs modern economies, for better or worse, not
state money.
Is it realistic for MMT to claim that the only reason modern
economies have unemployment is because politicians do not adopt MMT and
so let governments spend as much as necessary, backed by issuance of
state-controlled money? That is certainly not the view of Keynes or
Marx. Keynes reckoned unemployment emerged because of the lack of
investment by capitalists; Marx said the same (although the reserve army
of labour was the result of capital-bias in capitalist accumulation).
The difference between Marx and Keynes was what causes changes in
investment. Marx said profitability; Keynes said ‘animal spirits’ or
‘business confidence’. Both saw the faultlines within capitalism:
Keynes in the finance sector; Marx in capitalism as a whole. In
contrast, MMT reckons it is only the failure to allow the state to
expand the issuance of money!
But perhaps the most telling critique of MMT is that, because it has
no recognition of the capitalist sector in its circuit of money and only
the state and ‘the non-state’, it can tell us nothing about why and how
there are regular slumps in production and investment in modern
economies. On this issue, MMTers have the same position as orthodox
Keynesians: that it may be due to a lack of ‘effective demand’ or
‘animal spirits’ and it is nothing to do with any contradictions in the
capitalist mode of production itself. But for MMTers this issue is
irrelevant. MMTers take the same view as orthodox
Keynesian Paul Krugman, namely that it does not really matter what the
cause of a depression is; the main thing is to get out of it with
government spending – in the case of Krugman through judicious
government spending through bond issuance; in the case of MMT by
government spending financed by the issuance of money.
Call me old fashioned, but I think science works best by finding out
what causes things to happen to better understand what actions can be
usefully applied to prevent them (vaccination for diseases, for
example). Blindly hoping that government spending will do the trick is
hardly scientific. Indeed, much work has been done by Marxist economics
to show that it is the faultlines in the profitability of capital
that is the most compelling explanation of recurring crises, not lack
of demand or even austerity in public spending. And that implies action
to replace completely the profit-making monetary economy.
The answer to unemployment or the end of crises does not lie in the
simple recourse of issuing money, as MMT claims. MMT relies on what
Marx called “the tricks of circulation” – “the doctrine that
proposes tricks of circulation as a way of, on the one hand, avoiding
the violent character of these social changes and on the other, of
making these changes appear not to be a presupposition but gradual
result of these transformations in circulation”.
MMT claims that it has an endogenous theory of money, but in reality
it has an exogenous one, based on state issuance of money. It claims
that government spending can be expanded to any level necessary to
achieve full employment through money issuance, without any reference to
the productive activity of the non-state economy, in particular the
profitability of the capitalist sector. Indeed, according to MMT,
capitalism can be saved and achieve harmonious growth and full
employment by ‘tricks of circulation’. MMT ignores or hides the social
relations of exploitation of labour for profit. And by selling ‘snake
oil’ (MMT) instead, it misleads the labour movement away from
fundamental change.
If you have opinions about the subject matter of posts on this blog please share them. Do you have a story about how the system affects you at work school or home, or just in general? This is a place to share it.
Monday, February 4, 2019
Michael Roberts MMT 2 – the tricks of circulation
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment