by Michael Roberts
It is both appropriate and Ironic that, on the day that William
Nordhaus should get the Riksbank prize (also called Nobel) for his
contribution to the economics of climate change, the top scientific
body, the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), should
release its latest update on global warming. The report sets out the key practical differences between the Paris agreement’s two contrasting goals: to limit the increase of human-induced global warming to well below 2℃, and to “pursue efforts” to limit warming to 1.5℃.
The IPCC says that if we are to limit warming to 1.5℃, we must reduce
carbon dioxide emissions by 45% by 2030, reaching near-zero by around
2050. Whether we are successful primarily depends on the rate at which
government and non-state bodies take action to reduce emissions. Yet
despite the urgency, current national pledges under the Paris Agreement are not enough to remain within a 3℃ temperature limit, let alone 1.5℃.
Rapid action is essential and the next ten years will be crucial. In 2017, global warming breached 1℃.
If the planet continues to warm at the current rate of 0.2℃ per decade,
we will reach 1.5℃ of warming around 2040. At current emissions rates,
within the next 10 to 14 years there is a 2/3 chance we will have used
up our entire carbon budget for keeping to 1.5C. Global emissions of
carbon dioxide, methane and other greenhouse gases need to reach net
zero globally by around 2050. By 2050, 70-85% of electricity globally
will need to be supplied by renewables. Investment in low-carbon and
energy-efficient technologies will need to double, whereas investment in
fossil-fuel extraction will need to decrease by around a quarter.
Although the Paris Agreement aims to hold global warming as close to
1.5℃ as possible, that doesn’t mean it is a “safe” level. Communities
and ecosystems around the world have already suffered significant
impacts from the 1℃ of warming so far, and the effects at 1.5℃ will be
harsher still. Poverty and disadvantages will increase as temperatures rise to 1.5℃. Small island states, deltas and low-lying coasts are particularly vulnerable, with increased risk of flooding, and threats to freshwater supplies, infrastructure, and livelihoods.
Warming to 1.5℃ also poses a risk to global economic growth, with the
tropics and southern subtropics potentially being hit hardest. Extreme
weather events such as floods, heatwaves, and droughts will become more
frequent, severe, and widespread, with attendant costs in terms of
health care, infrastructure, and disaster response.
This is where William Nordhaus, a professor of economics at Yale University, comes in. He pioneered the economic analysis of climate change.
He is also a leading proponent of the use of carbon taxation to reduce
emissions, a policy approach preferred by many mainstream
economists. Nordhaus’ contribution was to develop a model that could
supposedly gauge the likely impact on economies from climate change.
Nordhaus constructed so-called integrated assessment models (IAMs) to
estimate the social cost of carbon (SCC) and evaluate alternative
abatement policies.
And this is where it becomes ironic. Nordhaus’ IAMs have flaws that
make them close to useless as tools for policy analysis. The IPCC
pointed out that estimates of losses resulting from a 2 °C increase in
mean global temperature above pre-industrial levels ranged from 0.2% to
2% of global gross domestic product. It admitted that the global
economic impacts are “difficult to estimate” and that attempts depend on
a large number of “disputable” assumptions. Moreover, many estimates do
not account for factors such as catastrophic changes and tipping points
ie where global warming gets out of control and damages economies much
more quickly and deeper than forecast.
Most IAMs struggle to incorporate the scale of the scientific risks,
such as the thawing of permafrost, release of methane, and other
potential tipping points. Furthermore, many of the largest potential
impacts are omitted, such as widespread conflict as a result of
large-scale human migration to escape the worst-affected areas.
IAMs are also used to calculate the social cost of carbon (SCC). They
attempt to model the incremental change in, or damage to, global
economic output resulting from 1 tonne of anthropogenic carbon dioxide
emissions or equivalent. These SCC estimates are used by policymakers in
cost–benefit analyses of climate-change-mitigation policies.
Because the IAMs omit so many of the big risks, SCC estimates are often way too low. As the IPCC acknowledged2,
published SCC estimates “lie between a few dollars and several hundreds
of dollars”. These values often depend crucially on the ‘discounting’
used to translate future costs to current dollars. The high discount
rates that predominate essentially assume that benefits to people in the
future are much less important than benefits today.
These discount rates are central to any discussion. Most current
models of climate-change impacts make two flawed assumptions: that
people will be much wealthier in the future and that lives in the future
are less important than lives now. The former assumption ignores the
great risks of severe damage and disruption to livelihoods from climate
change. The latter assumption is ‘discrimination by date of birth’. It
is a value judgement that is rarely scrutinized, difficult to defend and
in conflict with most moral codes.
The other role of IAMs — to estimate the costs of climate-change
mitigation — also suffers from major shortcomings. The IPCC’s mitigation
assessment concluded from its review of IAM outputs that the reduction
in emissions needed to provide a 66% chance of achieving the 2°C goal
would cut overall global consumption by between 2.9% and 11.4% in 2100.
This was measured relative to a ‘business as usual’ scenario. But growth
itself can be derailed by climate change from business-as-usual
emissions. So the business-as-usual baseline, against which costs of
action are measured, conveys a misleading message to policymakers that
fossil fuels can be consumed in ever greater quantities without any
negative consequences to growth itself.
The discount rate used to calculate the likely monetary damage to
economies is arbitrary. If we use a 3% discount rate, that means the
current rise in global warming would lead to $5trn of economic damage
(loss of GDP), but the cost in current money of global warming would be
no more than $400bn, about what China spends on hi-speed rail. So, on
this discount rate, global warming causes little economic damage and
thus the social cost of carbon (SCC) is only about $10/ton, so
mitigation action can be limited. This is what Nordhaus uses in his
model.
But why 3%? Nicholas Stern, of the famous Stern Review on climate
change, took Nordhaus’ data and applied a 1.4% discount rate. The SCC
then rises to $85/ton – meaning that it costs economies $85 for every
ton of Co2, or closer to $3trn now! If you take a median range discount
rate on likely damage, the SCC is probably about $50/t. But the
current carbon price is about $25/t. So the social cost is not being
‘internalised’ in any market prices.
The argument about the discount rate exposes the argument about the
future. The IAMs assume that the world economy will have a much larger
GDP in 50 years so that even if carbon emissions rise as the IPCC
predicts, governments can defer the cost of mitigation to the future.
And if you apply stringent carbon abatement measures eg ending all coal
production, you might lower growth rates and incomes and so make it more
difficult to mitigate in the future. Yes, that is what Nordhaus’ IAMs
can lead us to conclude.
These models exclude the obvious and now empirically backed evidence
that slower growth actually leads to less global warming. Tapia
Granados points out that “the evolution of CO2 emissions
and the economy in the past half century leaves no room to doubt that
emissions are directly connected with economic growth. The only periods
in which the greenhouse emissions that are destroying the stability of
the Earth climate have declined have been the years in which the world
economy has ceased growing and has contracted, i.e., during economic
crises. From the point of view of climate change, economic crises are a
blessing, while economic prosperity is a scourge.” Inexorable march toward utter climate disaster [f] (1)
And IAMs also exclude the feedback – namely that global warming leads
to more natural disasters, droughts and floods and thus to massive
disruption and migration of affected populations and thus a sharp
reduction in GDP growth rates. The world will not be much ‘richer’ in
the next generation if global warming goes unchecked. Finally, as with
all these neoclassical growth accounting models of which the IAM of
Nordhaus is one, there is no allowance for recurring crises of
production in capitalism or rising inequality of income and wealth.
Growth accounting is the mainstream version of explaining long-term
economic growth. Neoclassical theory assumes perfect competition and
free markets and it assumes what it should prove that capitalist
economic expansion will be harmonious and without crises as long as
markets are free and competition is operating.
Applying these microeconomic assumptions to long-term growth was the province of factor productivity models, originating with Solow and Swan in 1956.
Based on marginal utility theory, each factor of production (capital
and labour) contributed to growth according to its marginal
productivity. The problem with this factor accounting model was
two-fold.
First, the nature of ‘capital’ could not be defined or measured –
what was it: numbers of different machines or the present value of the
interest rate for borrowing ‘capital’? This led to the so-called Cambridge controversy,
where the neoclassical school was confounded by those who showed that
you needed a common measure of value (labour?), otherwise the definition
of capital was circular (namely its marginal productivity was the rate
of interest on borrowing, but the amount of capital was the present
value of the rate of interest!).
The second problem was that adding up the marginal contributions of
capital and labour factors to GDP growth would lead a ‘residual’; which
was designated as ‘technical innovation’, the productivity growth of all
the factors. This appeared to be ‘exogenous’ i.e. from outside the
market system of marginal productivity. Mainstream economics had no
explanation for technological innovation!
This is where the contribution of Paul Romer comes in. He developed an “endogenous growth model”,
where long-run economic growth is determined by forces that are
internal to the economic system, namely the ‘knowledge’ incorporated in
the workforce of an economy. Technological progress takes place through
innovations, in the form of new products, processes and markets, many of
which are the result of economic activities. Thus there are constant or
increasing returns to factors, not diminishing marginal ones. This
theory became popular with many reformist economists and politicians –
apparently, former adviser and minister in the British Gordon Brown
Labour government, Ed Balls, was a keen promoter.
Actually Romer was not the first to come up with this ‘endogenous’ model. That honour goes to the recently deceased Kenneth Arrow, the doyen of neoclassical economics.
Arrow recognised what any fool could see: that supply was affected by
demand but also demand was affected by supply. Innovation did not come
out of the sky but from the drive of companies to grow (or in the case
of Marxist theory, to make more profit and reduce labour costs). Of
course, the mainstream version of growth theory did not consider
profitability relevant to innovation but instead looked at aggregate
output.
However, the endogenous model is little better (and may be even
worse) than the exogenous model in explaining and accounting for
long-term growth in economies. Romer argues that the explanation for
why some countries grow faster and get richer than others is not more
investment in machines, or more labour power and skills; but more
‘ideas’. Whereas the old exogenous model predicted that growth would
slow as new investment in skills and capital yielded diminishing
returns, Romer’s New Growth Theory opened the window onto a sunnier
world view: a larger number of affluent people means more ideas, so
prosperity and population expansion might cause growth to speed up.
This is nonsense, of course. Capitalism does not work like that.
‘Ideas’ or innovations become the property of individual capitalist
companies; IPRs, patents etc are applied. The general distribution of
innovation only takes place through the rough and tumble of competition
and the battle for profit and market share. Innovation under capitalism
depends on profitability and if that is low or not there, or to be
given to all, then it won’t be applied. As one critic has pointed out,
Romer was very much a profit-making ‘entrepreneur’ himself, having
founded and sold on an online economic teaching company – so no open
spillover of ‘ideas’ there.
In a way, Romer recognises market forces and argues that governments
need to intervene to foster technological innovation, for example, by
investing in research and development and by writing patent laws that
provided sufficient rewards for new ideas without letting inventors
permanently monopolize those rewards. Thus we must correct and manage
the competitive struggle.
Romer is a professor of economics at New York University, but
recently he became chief economist at the World Bank for a short and
chequered period. It was a surprising appointment for an organisation
that is supposed to help poor countries end their poverty. That’s
because one of the conclusions that Romer took from his endogenous model
of ‘knowledge’ was that developing countries would benefit from
creating pockets within urban areas that are administered by a more
advanced country, so-called ‘charter cities’. The advanced country would
develop a small part of the country by introducing ‘good institutions’
and the benefits of development will spill over into the rest of the
economy.
Romer’s ideal example was Hong Kong. Rather than seeing Hong Kong’s signing away to Britain as unjust or humiliating for China, Romer saw it as an ‘intervention’
that has done much more to reduce poverty than any aid program and at a
much lower cost. Therefore, he concludes that the world needs more Hong
Kongs. The whole approach is that a country would gain from giving up
sovereignty to a more advanced nation that can better administer its
affairs.
But has China’s phenomenal growth over the last 40 years, taking 800m
people out of World Bank-defined poverty, needed ‘charter cities’ and
‘knowledge’ kindly administered by ‘advanced ‘ economies like the US.
Indeed, keeping imperialism out of China is part of the reason for
China’s growth success. Romer actually persuaded the government of
Madagascar to apply his development plan. It led to massive popular
uprisings against the President after he agreed to lease a part of
Madagascar to a South Korean corporation for 99 years!
Both the long-term growth models of Nordhaus and Romer rest on neoclassical free market theory. As Ben Fine pointed out nearly 20 years ago in his analysis of endogenous growth theory, it has “nothing
to do as such with an economy as a whole, other than in the trivial
sense of requiring at least two economic agents in order for exchange to
arise. Indeed, often implicitly and sometimes explicitly, the
literature takes a microeconomic theory and simply interprets it as
macroeconomics…In short, endogenous growth theory is heavily implicated
in the traditional and strengthening microeconomic foundations of
neoclassical economics.” Romer himself has recognised the failure of mainstream economics in his paper The trouble with macroeconomics, In that paper he goes on to trash all macroeconomic models for being unrealistic in their assumptions.
Both Nordhaus and Romer start with neoclassical theory and apply it
to analyse long-term growth. Their contributions are therefore stunted
for that reason. Factor of production models do not explain growth –
they leave ‘residuals’ and they cannot account for the nature of
‘capital’ – it’s either just things (machines) or accumulated interest.
And there is no connection between these models of growth and the
reality of capitalist accumulation for profit and the recurring crises
in investment and production in capitalist expansion.
Nordhaus and Romer are aware of these contradictions at the heart of
capitalism. They know that ‘free markets’ bring pollution and global
warming; and ‘markets’ will block innovation if left alone. But their
answer is to manage capitalism and try to persuade governments to do so.
As the world gets hotter faster, and growth gets slower, good luck with
that.
If you have opinions about the subject matter of posts on this blog please share them. Do you have a story about how the system affects you at work school or home, or just in general? This is a place to share it.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment