by Michael Roberts
This year’s Historical Materialism conference in London focused on the Russian revolution as well as the 150th anniversary of the publication of Marx’s Volume One of Capital. Naturally, I concentrated
on presentations that flowed from the latter rather than the former.
Indeed, the main plenary at HM was on Marx’s theory of value and
class – and the annual winner of the Isaac Deutscher book prize
announced at the HM was William Clare Roberts’ Marx’s Inferno, which seemed to be a ‘political theory’ of capital seen through the prism of Dante’s famous poem. Maybe, more on that later.
The plenary speakers were Moishe Postone, Michael Heinrich and David
Harvey – an impressive line-up of heavyweight Marxist academics. Postone is co-director of the Chicago Center for Contemporary Theory
and faculty member of the Chicago Center for Jewish Studies. His
30-min speech was difficult to understand, being couched in polysyllabic
academic jargon. But I think the gist of it was that we cannot consider
the class struggle under capitalism as just between exploited workers
and capitalists any longer, as it now involves race, creed and gender
and a new populism of the right. So we need to rethink Marx’s theory of
class.
For this reason, “orthodox Marxism” is a hindrance. The old meaning
of class struggle is not essential. As for Marx’s theory of value, it
is specific to capitalism, but it has changed and exploitation is now
over the amount of time we all have rather than over the production of
surplus value. Now I think that is the gist of what he said, but
frankly, I cannot be sure because Postone’s exposition was so
incomprehensible.
The next speaker was
Michael Heinrich, the well-known German expert of Marx’s Capital and
close researcher of Marx’s original writings in the so-called MEGA
project. Now readers of this blog will know that Heinrich and I
have debated before on whether Marx’s law of the tendency of the rate of
profit is logical and whether Marx himself dropped it; and we published on this issue.
In his presentation, Heinrich agreed with Postone that value is a
category specific to capitalism, but he reckons that Marx changed his
conception of both class and value over his lifetime. So it is not
possible to pull quotes from Marx like random rocks in a stone quarry.
Each quote must be placed in its context and time. For example, Marx’s
definition of class struggle as found in the Communist Manifesto in 1848
differs with his later definitions of class at the end of Capital
Volume 3.
Similarly, Marx’s concept of value changed over time. Early on,
value is seen to come from the production process and the exploitation
of labour power by capital. Later on, Marx revised this view to argue
that value was only created at the point of exchange into money.
Similarly, Marx thought that a rising organic composition of capital
would lead to a fall in the rate of profit, but later he recognised that
more machines could raise the rate of surplus value and so the rate of
profit may not fall.
Heinrich has the advantage over us in reading Marx’s original words
in German, but they remind his interpretations of Marx’s meaning.
Heinrich, in effect, argues that value is not a material substance,
namely the expenditure of human energy in labour that can be measured in
labour time, but only exists in the form of money. In my view and in
the view of many other Marxists, this denies the role of exploitation of
labour in production, which comes first. Yes, you can only see value
in the form of money, but then you cannot see electricity until the
light comes on, but that does not mean it does not exist before the
light glows. For an excellent critique of Heinrich’s interpretation of
Marx’s value theory, see G Carchedi’s book, Behind the Crisis, chapter 2).
Does any of this matter, you might say? Are we not just discussing
how many angels are there on the head of a needle, as medieval Catholic
theologians did? Well, yes. But I think there are some consequences
from deciding that value is only created in exchange and also that class
struggle is not really centred (any longer) on workers and capitalists
in the production process. For me, such theories lead to the idea that
crises under capitalism are caused by faults in the ‘circulation of
money and credit’ and not in the contradictions of capitalism between
productivity and profitability in the production of surplus value, as I
think Marx argued. And the revisions of the nature of class struggle
could lead to the removal of the working class as the agent for
socialist change.
There is a similar problem with David Harvey’s presentation. Again,
Harvey has made a massive contribution to expounding and defending
Marx’s ideas as expressed in Capital to explain the workings of the
capitalist mode of production. I
have presented my critique of Harvey’s more novel propositions on this
blog before and he has also criticised my ‘orthodox’ view.
In his presentation, Harvey again looked to be ‘innovatory’ in an
attempt to raise new categories in Capital. Yes, value is
‘phantom-like’ (can’t be seen), but objective (i.e. real) and only
appears as money. But Harvey wants us to consider new terms like
‘anti-value’. What does Harvey mean by this? Apparently, money and
credit can be created without the backing of value. Marx called this
‘fictitious capital’ because it was not real capital based on the
production of value and surplus value by the exploitation of labour, but
merely the title to assets that may or may not be supported by new
value. In that sense, investment in financial assets produces
fictitious profits.
Now Harvey wants to change the name of this category to ‘anti-value’
because he thinks that in doing so it can show that there are obstacles
to the flow of capital (value) in the realisation of value. Thus crises
can originate or be caused from breaks in the circuit of capital
outside the production process itself. Similarly, Harvey came up with
what he called ‘value regimes’. ‘World money’ as represented by gold no
longer controls the value of fiat money (money ‘printed’ and backed by
governments), particularly after the US dollar came off the gold
standard in 1971. So now we have ‘value regimes’ like the dollar area,
the euro and more recently, the Chinese yuan. Again, I think all this
was saying was that various economic national state powers are trying
gain the biggest shares of global value and in so far as they are
successful, their currencies will be stronger relative to others over
time. I failed to see why we needed new terms or concepts to ‘explain’
this. But there we are.
Of course, things have changed over the last 150 years since Marx
formulated his critique of capitalism and political economy and
published Capital. Capitalism is now global, finance capital has
expanded dramatically, imperialist power blocs have developed and
capital has become ever more concentrated and centralised. But it seems
to me that the laws of motion in the capitalist mode of production have
not so fundamentally changed that we need new categories to explain
them; or we need to drop Marx’s basic value theory or his main law of
the contradiction between productivity and profitability to explain
crises and instead search for other explanations in the money and credit
circuit.
If we do that, then we also reduce the role of the proletariat as the
main agency for revolutionary change. And in my view, it still is, if
only by the absence of success in the last 150 years.
Revolutions based
on the peasantry (China) or isolated in one country (Russia) have not
delivered socialism even if they have removed capitalism, for a while.
Only the global proletariat in unity can do that.
The idea that Marx’s theory of value and crises is out of date and
needed amending was the theme of my own paper at HM. I quoted John
Maynard Keynes in commenting that Capital was “an obsolete textbook
which I know to be not only scientifically erroneous but without
interest or application for the modern world”. I wanted to defend
Marx against this view of Keynes, which is still prevalent not only in
bourgeois analysis, but also in recent biographies of Marx by former Marxist historians who claim that Marx was a man of 19th century with little to tell us about the 21st.
My paper above all aimed to show that Keynesian ideas have nothing in
common with Marx’s critique of capitalism and are thoroughly designed
to restore capitalism in crisis and make it work better. HM London November 2017
This, I think, is important, because Keynesian theory and policies
dominate the minds of the labour movement everywhere, as though they
were a workable and radical alternative, while Marxist theory is
ignored.
Of course, this is no accident because if you accept Marx’s critique
of capitalism, you are compelled to require a revolutionary
transformation of the capitalist mode of production – something that
remains frightening, not just to the leaders of the labour movement, but
also to many activists who fear the risks involved in revolutionary
change.
My paper argued that, contrary to Keynes’ view, the labour theory of
value provides a logical and empirically verifiable explanation of the
capitalist mode of production, while, in contrast, the mainstream
‘marginalist’ theory is false, indeed unfalsifiable. Marx’s great
discovery about capitalism is that it is a system of exploitation of
labour power to appropriate value produced by workers as surplus value
or profit through sale on the market for commodities. That is where
profit comes from. Keynes, like all mainstream economics, denied profit
is the result of unpaid labour. For him, profit is the marginal return
on investment and justified to the capitalist.
Marx’s theory of crises means that rising productivity of labour
through increased investment in means of production relative to labour
will lead to the contradictory fall in profitability, engendering
recurring crises. Keynes, instead, saw slumps or depressions as due to a
collapse in the ‘animal spirits’ of entrepreneurs and/or to too high
interest rates charged by financiers. Crises are a ‘technical problem’
that can be corrected by boosting the ‘confidence’ of capitalists and
lowering interest rates, or in the extreme, getting governments to spend
to prime the pump of private industry.
For Keynes, once such measures are used to deal with these occasional
slumps, then capitalism will be set fair for a golden future where
hours of toil will fall dramatically with the use of technology;
scarcity and poverty would disappear; and the main problem would be how
to use our leisure time. Well, now 80 years after Keynes argued this,
more than 2bn people are in dire poverty, inequality has never been
greater, technology is threatening to take away many jobs and the
average working life has not fallen at all. Moreover, the Keynesian
prescriptions of easy money (QE) and government spending have signally
failed to revive capitalism in the major economies since the Great
Recession. The Long Depression, as I have called it, remains.
Indeed, in my session, veteran French Marxist Francois Chesnais presented his thoughts from his book, Finance Capital Today,
which was short listed for the Deutscher prize. Chesnais argued that
the current depression would never end. The rate of profit globally is
still falling and global debt is steadily rising. The Great Recession
has not ‘cleansed’ the system. And now global warming threatens to
destroy the planet.
Now I am not quite so ‘pessimistic’ (or is it optimistic?) that
capitalism is in its last throes. But it is possible that capitalism
could sink into ‘barbarism’ or the collapse of living standards, as the
Roman slave empire did after 400AD, without being replaced by a new mode
of production. As Carchedi put it in a recent paper at the Capital.150
symposium, ‘the old is dying but the new cannot be born’ (Gramsci). But
capitalism could also stagger on with some revival in profitability
after new slumps and the renewed opportunity to exploit new sources of
labour in Africa and the periphery. It will require the action of the
global working class to achieve socialism. It won’t come just because
capitalism flounders economically.
Marx’s Capital provides us with the clearest and most compelling
analysis of the nature of the capitalist mode of production and also its
irreconcilable contradictions that show why capitalism is transient and
cannot last forever, contrary to what the apologists for capital claim.
I don’t think we need to invent new and often confusing terms or
categories to explain modern capitalism 150 years since Capital was
published; or deny the role of exploitation in the creation of value at
the heart of capitalism; or reduce the role of the global proletariat in
ending it.
If you have opinions about the subject matter of posts on this blog please share them. Do you have a story about how the system affects you at work school or home, or just in general? This is a place to share it.
No comments:
Post a Comment