by Michael Roberts
Recently, mainstream economists have been debating yet again
why ‘economics’ was unable to see the global financial crash coming
and/or provide effective policies to end what I have described as the
Long Depression that has endured since the end of the Great Recession in
2009.
Mainstream economists John Quiggin and Henry Farrell summed up the debate in a paper: “some
blame non-academic economists. Others blame prominent academics. Others
still say that economic advice doesn’t really matter, because
politicians will pay attention only to the advice that they wanted to
hear anyway.”
But Quiggin and Farrell reckon the real reason that mainstream
economics failed to be of any use was the lack of agreement among
economists on what to do. Economists could not agree on whether
austerity was good or bad for the economy; or on whether economists had
any influence over politicians. And the reason for this lack of
agreement was not due to differences on theory but to “sociology”. By this they mean that mainstream economists are not pure objective ‘economists’ but are “deeply bound up with the political systems that they live within”
As I also pointed out in my book, The Long Depression, Quiggin and Farrell explain that, “prominent
academic economists, far more than other social scientists, are likely
to go back and forth between universities and roles in the Treasury
Department, Federal Reserve, International Monetary Fund and World Bank.
This means that economics has far more political clout than other
social sciences, but it also has reshaped the profession, turning
external policy influence into an important form of internal
disciplinary prestige.”
In other words, economists with jobs in government and the central bank go with the flow (from the forces of capital): “So
the world of economic politics and the world of economic thought are
deeply intertwined. Channels of influence rarely flow only in one
direction, as some economists have discovered to their dismay.”
This conclusion seemed to surprise as well as upset Quiggin and
Farrell. Yet, if they had read Marx, they would have expected nothing
else. As Marx pointed out 150 years ago, in a footnote to the chapter
on Commodities and Money in Capital, while making the distinction
between classical economics and vulgar economics: “Once for all I
may here state, that by classical political economy, I understand that
economy which, since the time of W. Petty, has investigated the real
relations of production in bourgeois society, in contradistinction to
vulgar economy, which deals with appearances only, ruminates without
ceasing on the materials long since provided by scientific economy, and
there seeks plausible explanations of the most obtrusive phenomena, for
bourgeois daily use, but for the rest, confines itself to systematizing
in a pedantic way, and proclaiming for everlasting truths, the trite
ideas held by the self-complacent bourgeoisie with regard to their own
world, to them the best of all possible worlds (p. 174 – 175).
Even earlier, Frederick Engels had anticipated the trend of economics in his Outlines Of A Critique Of Political Economy in 1843: “The
nearer to our time the economists whom we have to judge, the more
severe must our judgment become. For while Smith and Malthus found only
scattered fragments, the modern economists had the whole system complete
before them: the consequences had all been drawn; the contradictions
came clearly enough to light, yet they did not come to examine the
premises and still accepted the responsibility for the whole system. The
nearer the economists come to the present time, the further they depart
from honesty”.
And in Theories of Surplus Value, Marx described “the vulgar
economists—by no means to be confused with the economic investigators we
have been criticising—translate the concepts, motives, etc., of the
representatives of the capitalist mode of production who are held in
thrall to this system of production and in whose consciousness only its
superficial appearance is reflected. They translate them into a
doctrinaire language, but they do so from the standpoint of the ruling
section, i.e., the capitalists, and their treatment is therefore not
naïve and objective, but apologetic.”
In other words, all the obstruse theory presented by modern
mainstream economics is presented as purely neutral, unbiased and
logical, but in reality it is not “naïve and objective” but merely an
apologia for the capitalist mode of production. “It was henceforth,” Marx wrote, “no
longer a question whether this theorem or that was true, but whether it
was useful to capital or harmful, expedient or inexpedient, politically
dangerous or not. Pure, selfless research gave way to battles between
hired scribblers, and genuine scientific research was replaced by the
bad conscience and the evil intent of apologetic”. Capital, vol. 1, p. 97
Recently, two mainstream economists (Identification in Macroeconomics Emi Nakamura and Jon Steinsson ´ ∗ Columbia University September 30, 2017) started their paper: “Any
scientific enterprise needs to be grounded in solid empirical knowledge
about the phenomenon in question. Milton Friedman put this well in his
Nobel lecture in 1976: “In order to recommend a course of action to
achieve an objective, we must first know whether that course of action
will in fact promote the objective. Positive scientific knowledge that
enables us to predict the consequences of a possible course of action is
clearly a prerequisite for the normative judgment whether that course
of action is desirable.”
Sounds good, but unfortunately, “Many of the main empirical
questions in macroeconomics are the same as they were 80 years ago when
macroeconomics came into being as a separate sub-discipline of economics
in the wake of the Great Depression. These are questions such as: What
are the sources of business cycle fluctuations? How does monetary policy
affect the economy? How does fiscal policy affect the economy? Why do
some countries grow faster than others? Those new to our field or viewing
it from afar may be tempted to ask: How can it be that after all this
time we don’t know the answers to these questions?” Indeed!
However, the authors remain optimistic. For them, the problem is not
that economists are locked into an apologia for the capitalist system,
but that it is difficult to ‘identify’ the right variables in any causal
analysis. In other words, economics is a positivist science like
physics but it is just behind in its understanding of ‘the economy’
compared to physics because of the extra difficulty in empirical work.
Economics could progress in the same way that ‘natural science’ has. “Macroeconomics
and meteorology are similar in certain ways. First, both fields deal
with highly complex general equilibrium systems. Second, both field have
trouble making long-term predictions. For this reason, considering the
evolution of meteorology is helpful for understanding the potential
upside of our research in macroeconomics. In the olden days, before the
advent of modern science, people spent a lot of time praying to the rain
gods and doing other crazy things meant to improve the weather. But as
our scientific understanding of the weather has improved, people have
spent a lot less time praying to the rain gods and a lot more time
watching the weather channel. “
Unfortunately for the authors, such progress towards the truth will
not take place in economics. To think so is just naïve. To quote Milton
Friedman as the epitomy of unbiased, objective positivist scientific
analysis demonstrates that naivety. Friedman was the peer example of an
ideologist for capital, including his job as an advisor for General
Pinochet after his coup against the democratically elected government of
Chile in the 1970s (see my book, The Great Recession for more on
Friedman).
Yes, economics is a science, in my view. More accurately, as Marx
says, it is political economy, the study of the social relations of the
capitalist mode of production. Yes, we need to test economic theories against the facts by identifying the causal variables. Indeed, we should make predictions to test our theories.
But do not expect the body of mainstream economics to do so in any
systematic way. It has been hopelessly distorted by the need to
preserve and defend the capitalist system. As the authors say: “Policy
discussions about macroeconomics today are, unfortunately, highly
influenced by ideology. Politicians, policy makers and even some
academics have held strong views about how macroeconomic policy works
that are not based on evidence but rather on faith.”
They remain confident, however, that: “The only reason why this
sorry state of affairs persists is that our evidence regarding the
consequences of different macroeconomic policies is still highly
imperfect and open to serious criticism. Despite this, we are hopeful
regarding the future of our field. We see that solid empirical knowledge
about how the economy works at the macroeconomic level is being
uncovered at an increasingly rapid rate. Over time, as we amass a better
understanding of how the economy works, there will be less and less
scope for belief in “rain gods” in macroeconomics and more and more
reliance on solid scientific facts.”
Unfortunately, as the global financial crash and the Great Recession
showed, mainstream economics has not progressed as much as
meteorologists in predicting storms and hurricanes. Economists still
look to the raingods because it’s a matter of faith not reason.
If you have opinions about the subject matter of posts on this blog please share them. Do you have a story about how the system affects you at work school or home, or just in general? This is a place to share it.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment