by Michael Roberts
The election of a new leader of the UK’s opposition Labour party
has provoked a flurry of interest in the international media and among
economists. That’s because the new leader, Jeremy Corbyn and his newly
appointed finance spokesman, John McDonnell, have been considered as
‘avowed Marxists’.
That is certainly the case for McDonnell. He is an ‘avowed Marxist’
because he says he is. On the day of his big keynote economics speech
at Labour’s annual conference this week, he said that “If you look
at our capitalist system, one of the definitive analysts of how it works
– not whether it is condemned, or whether it is right or wrong, just
the mechanics of how it works, when it was formed and how it would be
developed – actually was Marx.” He went on “If you look at
most of the institutions that are teaching economics today. Marx has
come back in to fashion because people have gone back to his analysis of
just the basics of how the system works. People might disagree with his
conclusions about what to do with the system, but actually to
understand how the system works he comes up with some interesting
analyses that have been built in to traditional and fairly classical
economics.”
However, note that John McDowell makes a distinction between Marx’s
‘interesting analysis’ of the capitalist system i.e. what is wrong with
it, and “his conclusions about what to do”. Thus Marxist policies for dealing with capitalism do not necessarily flow from his analysis, it seems. What policies do? Well, apparently, it is Keynesian prescriptions. Thus McDonnell has announced a panel of economic advisers,
including international luminaries like Joseph Stiglitz and Thomas
Piketty, to help on policy. This committee is drawn from the Keynesian
mainstream and its heterodox wings, but not Marxist.
I’m sure that it looks like a very good political ploy to involve
leading economists in Labour’s economic plans. No doubt it is hoped that
it will disarm criticism from the financial media and big business when
a Noble prize winner and the economist of the moment are on the
committee. But this reminds me more of the approach of Greece’s Syriza,
which started out with a Marxist ‘analysis’ of Greek capitalism but
which, according to Yanis Varoufakis and Costas Lapavitsas, should be put aside when it comes to policy because Keynesian economics is more relevant ‘in practice’.
You see the problem is a ‘lack of demand’, not a lack of profitability.
So, in a slump, Keynesian prescriptions call for more government
spending or a reversal of ‘austerity’ (in the current parlance), so that
spending boosts employment and incomes and restores household
consumption (and investment?) as the means to recovery. That means
running budget deficits through more government borrowing (issuance of
more bonds).
Keynesians generally dismiss those (Austerians and neo-liberals) who
worry that, as a result, spiralling government debt will lead to a new
crisis as governments find they cannot service their debt except at
unaffordable interest rates (Greece and the peripheral Eurozone
economies, Puerto Rico etc). You see, for Keynesians, one man’s debt is another’s asset.
So the only problem is if it is foreigners who own the debt. If they
demand repayment, they can cripple the currency. This is the view of
Paul Krugman in the US and Simon Wren-Lewis, the British Keynesian guru,
now part of McDonnell’s advisory team.
But debt does matter.
One of the features of the global financial crash was the massive rise
in private sector debt (household and corporate) before the credit
crunch in 2007. That debt rose as capitalist economies tried to keep
profitability of capital and economic growth up through a low interest
rate, credit-fuelled bubble in unproductive sectors of finance and
property. The private credit bit (not the profitability bit) is the
Minskyite view of the crisis as expounded in particular by Steve Keen and Anastasia Nesvetailova (one of the McDonnell’s new advisers).
But as I have explained on many occasions in this blog, the credit boom of the 2000s was a response to declining profitability of capital in the productive sectors
of the US, UK and other major economies from the end of the 1990s. It
staved off a major slump, only to create an even larger one in 2008-9.
That’s private sector debt. But the same issue applies to public
sector debt. If the owners of this debt (banks, hedge funds, pension
funds, insurance companies) decide that they want to get their money
back or demand lots more in interest to renew loans or buy government
bonds, they can cripple the ability of a government to pay for welfare
benefits and public services, let alone investment in roads, hospitals
and schools.
Debt does matter in a capitalist economy: capitalists owe to other
capitalists; households owe to finance capitalists; and governments owe
to finance capitalists. The holders of this debt expect a return and
prompt repayments. Under a predominantly state-owned and planned
economy, state companies, households and governments would owe to other
state companies. So the decisions on the cost of borrowing and
repayment terms could be decided as part of a national plan and not by
the ‘market’ and on the profitability of (finance) capital.
Ironically, having selected Keynesians and Minskyites for his ‘team’, John McDonnell has made it clear from the start that he is not a ‘deficit denier’.
By this, he means that he does accept that running government budget
deficits cannot be ignored, as the Keynesians reckon. As McDonnell put
it: “We accept we are going to have to live within our means and we always will do – full stop.” And he advocates signing up to the Conservative government’s fiscal charter that will make it a law that government’s must ‘balance the books’ over the ‘business cycle’. “We
will support the charter. We will support the charter on the basis we
are going to want to balance the books, we do want to live within our
means and we will tackle the deficit.”
This is clearly a political ploy by McDonnell to avoid the charge
being made by the Conservatives that Labour ,when in government, allowed
deficits to get out of control and thus caused the crisis and the Great
Recession and that Labour has no regard for ‘balancing the books’. This
charge, of course, is nonsense and a downright lie. Actually, when in
government, Labour generally ran lower budget deficits than the
Conservatives and under ‘prudent’ finance minister and PM Gordon Brown,
government spending was kept well under control, as Ann Pettifor, one of McDonnell’s new Keynesian advisers, has pointed out.
The UK’s budget deficit spiralled only when the global financial
crash came and British banks had to be bailed out with taxpayer’s money
(borrowing). This prompted Gordon Brown to tell the British parliament
that he had ‘saved the world’ (a slip of hubris, meaning he had saved
the banks). The
current government deficit, still way higher than in other G7 economies
under the Conservatives and government debt still rising towards 100%
of GDP, was the product of the capitalist crisis (the financial meltdown and the ensuing Great Recession).
McDonnell says that this deficit and the government debt can be
reduced not by cutting welfare and public services as the Conservatives
have done and are doing. It is a political choice. Instead it can be
done by raising taxes on the rich (reversing cuts in corporation tax and
inheritance tax), reducing ‘corporate welfare’ (around £90bn a year),
dealing aggressively with tax evasion
and avoidance by the likes of Vodafone, Amazon, Google and Starbucks
(worth up to £120bn a year). And Labour under McDonnell would also
stimulate economic growth by borrowing to invest in infrastructure
projects. McDonnell also estimates that £80-100bn could be saved (over
30 years, mind) by scrapping the Trident nuclear submarine programme due
for renewal next year.
Laudable as these aims are, as I have pointed out in a previous post,
much of these tax gathering measures may not deliver enough extra
revenue to close the deficit – if that is the aim, apart from making
inequality of income and wealth, ludicrously high, just a little less
extreme. It
has been pointed out that it will be very difficult to raise the
necessary extra £30bn a year in taxes without hitting middle-income
earners – unless UK economic growth takes off from its current 2.0-2.5% a year expansion rate.
The circle could easily be squared if private sector incomes (wages
and profits) rose substantially faster to deliver much higher tax
revenues. But that is not going to happen under a predominantly
capitalist economy where profitability is key to investment, employment
and income growth. British capitalism has already failed to invest,
preferring to pocket its profits and/or speculate in financial assets or
invest abroad. And that’s with the lowest corporate tax rate among the
major economies, as Conservative finance minister George Osborne likes
to boast. Higher taxes on the capitalist sector, namely the big
companies that invest and employ the bulk of the British economy and
people, will only mean a further failure to invest.
The ‘new’ Labour leadership replacing the ‘old’ (‘New Labour’,
neo-liberal) leadership is pledged to expand public investment in
infrastructure, ‘green’ sectors and in housing and transport. This will
undoubtedly help to sustain economic activity apart from helping the
majority instead of the 1%. But Corbyn and McDonnell’s National
Investment Bank will not be enough to deliver sufficiently faster growth
as long as the UK economy is still dominated in its strategic sectors
by capitalist profit-making companies in the City of London (privatised
banking, insurance and pension funds); by large pharma and aerospace
companies; telecoms (BT), house-building companies and transport (rail,
bus and airlines) etc.
Along with a National Investment Bank (and fully state-owned
banking), what is needed is a National Plan for investment, employment
and services based on a predominantly state-owned economy,
democratically controlled and operated. But that is the Marxist
prescription from the ‘interesting’ Marxist analysis of the capitalist
economy. Instead, the new Labour leadership likes the Marxist
‘analysis’ but looks to Keynesian ‘solutions’.
Capitalism has regular and recurring crises – that’s one unique
conclusion from the Marxist economic analysis, something not accepted or
recognised by mainstream, Keynesian or Minskyite economic theory. As I
argued in a previous post,
British capitalism, along with global capital, is likely to enter
another slump before the next British general election in 2020. Indeed,
McDonnell has also noted that many of the features that led to the last
Great Recession: a credit boom, a housing bubble, bank speculation etc,
have re-emerged.
Keynesians did not see the last slump (the Great Recession) coming
and did not have the policies to deal with it, at least in the interests
of the majority. So relying on Keynesian policies to handle or avoid
the next slump, even as a political ploy, may be a hostage to fortune
for the new Labour leadership.
If you have opinions about the subject matter of posts on this blog please share them. Do you have a story about how the system affects you at work school or home, or just in general? This is a place to share it.
Wednesday, September 30, 2015
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment