by Michael Roberts
I did a recent post on Paul Mason’s new book, Postcapitalism,
which argued that the internet, automation, robots and artificial
intelligence were creating a new economy which could not be controlled
by capitalism. According to Mason, new forces are at work that were
replacing the old class struggle between capital and the proletariat, as
Marx saw it, with a network of communities. Technology and the network
would lead to a post-capitalist (socialist?) world that could not be
stopped
I disagreed that the new technology would replace the ‘old forms’ of
class struggle or for that matter regular and recurrent economic crises
under capitalism would dissipate towards a high productivity, low
working day as capitalism ‘withered away’.
But this debate has encouraged me to do something that I have been
wanting to deal with in more detail for some time. Namely, what are the
implications of these new technologies for capitalism? In particular,
are robots and artificial intelligence set to take over the world of
work and thus the economy in the next generation and what does this mean
for jobs and living standards for people? Will it mean socialist
utopia in our time (the end of human toil and a superabundant harmonious
society) or capitalist dystopia (more intense crises and class
conflict)?
It’s a big subject. So let me first make a few definitions. By
robots, I mean machines that can replace human labour through the use of
computer programmes that direct the movement of machine parts to carry
out tasks, both simple and increasingly complex.
The International Federation of Robotics (IFR) considers a machine as
an industrial robot if it can be programmed to perform physical,
production-related tasks without the need of a human controller.
Industrial robots dramatically increase the scope for replacing human
labour compared to older types of machines, since they reduce the need
for human intervention in automated processes. Typical applications of
industrial robots include assembling, dispensing, handling, processing
(for instance, cutting), and welding – all of which are prevalent in
manufacturing industries – as well as harvesting (in agriculture) and
inspecting of equipment and structures (common in power plants).
Industrial robotics has the potential to change manufacturing
by increasing precision and productivity without incurring higher
costs. 3D printing could generate a new ecosystem of companies providing
printable designs on the web, making everyday products endlessly
customizable. The so-called ‘Internet of Things’ offers the possibility
to connect machines and equipment to each other and to common networks,
allowing for manufacturing facilities to be fully monitored and operated
remotely.
In health care and life sciences, data driven
decision-making, which allows the collection and analysis of large
datasets, is already changing R&D, clinical care, forecasting and
marketing. The use of big data in health care has led to highly
personalized treatments and medicines. The infrastructure
sector, which had no gain in labour productivity in the last 20 years,
could be greatly enhanced by, for example: the creation of Intelligent Transportation Systems,
which could massively increase asset utilization; the introduction of
smart grids, which could help save on power infrastructure costs and
reduce the likelihood of costly outages; and efficient demand
management, which could dramatically lower per-capita energy use.
Which of these emerging technologies have the greatest potential to drive improvements in productivity? McKinsey Global Institute (MGI) (2013)
reckon that ‘technologies that matter’ are technologies that have the
greatest potential to deliver substantial economic impact and disruption
in the next decade. Those that make their list are rapidly advancing
(e.g. gene-sequencing technology); have a broad reach (e.g. mobile
internet); have the potential to create an economic impact (e.g.
advanced robotics) and have the potential to change the status quo (e.g.
energy storage technology). MGI estimates that the economic impact of
these technologies – derived from falls in their prices and their
diffusion and improved efficiency – to be between $14 and $33 trillion
per year in 2025, led by mobile internet, the automation of knowledge
work, the internet of things and cloud technology.
John Lanchester in a brilliant essay summed this up (Lanchester):
“Computers have got dramatically more powerful and become so cheap that
they are effectively ubiquitous. So have the sensors they use to
monitor the physical world. The software they run has improved
dramatically too. We are, Brynjolfsson and McAfee argue, on the verge of
a new industrial revolution, one which will have as much impact on the
world as the first one. Whole categories of work will be transformed by
the power of computing, and in particular by the impact of robots.”
By artificial intelligence (AI), is meant machines that do not just
carry out pre-programmed instructions but learn more new programmes and
instruction by experience and by new situations. AI means in effect
robots who learn and increase their intelligence. This could happen to
the point where robots can make more robots with increasing
intelligence. Indeed, some argue that AI will soon surpass the
intelligence of human beings. This is called the ‘singularity’ – the
moment when human beings are no longer the most intelligent things on
the planet. Moreover, robots could even develop the senses and form of
human beings, thus being ‘sentient’.
But before we get into science (or science fiction?), let us consider
first things first. If robots and AI are fast on their way, will this
mean a huge of loss of jobs or alternatively new sectors for employment
and the need to work fewer hours?
In recent work, Graetz and Michaels
looked at 14 industries (mainly manufacturing industries, but also
agriculture and utilities) in 17 developed countries (including European
countries, Australia, South Korea, and the US) They found that
industrial robots increase labour productivity, total factor
productivity, and wages. At the same time, while industrial robots had
no significant effect on total hours worked, there is some evidence that
they reduced the employment of low skilled workers, and, to a lesser
extent, also middle skilled workers. Full paper here .
So in essence, robots did not reduce toil (hours of work) for those who
had work, on the contrary. But they did lead to a loss of jobs for the
unskilled and even those with some skills. So more toil, not less
hours; and more unemployment.
Two Oxford economists, Carl Benedikt Frey and Michael Osborne,
looked at the likely impact of technological change on a sweeping range
of 702 occupations, from podiatrists to tour guides, animal trainers to
personal finance advisers and floor sanders. Their conclusions were
frightening: “According to our estimates, about 47 percent
of total US employment is at risk. We further provide evidence that
wages and educational attainment exhibit a strong negative relationship
with an occupation’s probability of computerisation…. Rather
than reducing the demand for middle-income occupations, which has been
the pattern over the past decades, our model predicts that
computerisation will mainly substitute for low-skill and low-wage jobs
in the near future. By contrast, high-skill and high-wage occupations
are the least susceptible to computer capital.’ Lanchester summed up their conclusions: “So the poor will be hurt, the middle will do slightly better than it has been doing, and the rich – surprise! – will be fine.”
Lanchester makes the point in his essay that the robotic world could
lead, not to a ‘post-capitalist’ utopia but instead to a ‘Pikettyworld’ “in which capital is increasingly triumphant over labour.” And he quotes the huge profits that the large techno companies are making. “In
1960, the most profitable company in the world’s biggest economy was
General Motors. In today’s money, GM made $7.6 billion that year. It
also employed 600,000 people. Today’s most profitable company employs
92,600. So where 600,000 workers would once generate $7.6 billion in
profit, now 92,600 generate $89.9 billion, an improvement in
profitability per worker of 76.65 times. Remember, this is pure profit
for the company’s owners, after all workers have been paid. Capital
isn’t just winning against labour: there’s no contest. If it were a
boxing match, the referee would stop the fight.”
But looking at the profits of companies that have seized the value
created by labour in the new sectors is not necessarily a guide to the
health of capital as a whole. Is capitalism as a whole having a new
lease of life as a result? After all, overall investment growth is very
low in the current long depression and productivity growth as a result
also. See my posts on productivity and investment.
Robots do not do away with the contradictions within capitalist
accumulation. The essence of capitalist accumulation is that to
increase profits and accumulate more capital, capitalists want to
introduce machines that can boost the productivity of each employee and
reduce costs compared to competitors. This is the great revolutionary
role of capitalism in developing the productive forces available to
society.
But there is a contradiction. In trying to raise the productivity of
labour with the introduction of technology, there is process of labour
shedding. New technology replaces labour. Yes, increased productivity
might lead to increased production and open up new sectors for
employment to compensate. But over time, a capital-bias or labour
shedding means less new value is created (as labour is the only form of
value) relative to the cost of invested capital. There is a tendency
for profitability to fall as productivity rises. In turn, that leads
eventually to a crisis in production that halts or even reverses the
gain in production from the new technology. This is solely because
investment and production depend on the profitability of capital in our
modern mode of production.
So an economy increasingly dominated by the internet of things and
robots under capitalism will mean more intense crises and greater
inequality rather than super-abundance and prosperity. In my next post
on this subject, I’ll consider whether the world of robots making robots
with ever-increasing intelligence – and perhaps eventually no human
labour employed – would end the law of value and recurrent crises under
capitalism.
If you have opinions about the subject matter of posts on this blog please share them. Do you have a story about how the system affects you at work school or home, or just in general? This is a place to share it.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment