Saturday, March 16, 2013

Workers, punks and the euro crisis

by Michael Roberts

I’ve just got back from Slovenia, where I gave a lecture on the Euro crisis to the Institute of Labour Studies (http://dpu.mirovni-institut.si/roberts2013.php).  The Institute was set up by a group of  economics  students who support a Marxist analysis.  They are doing a great job in trying to develop Marxist economic theory by inviting leading Marxist scholars and writers to do lectures or participate in conferences.  The Institute is really a spin-off from Slovenia’s unique Workers and Punks University (http://dpu.mirovni-institut.si/index-e.php), a sort of alternative university formed by radical young people to present an alternative to conventional educational institutions and dominant ideas that there is no alternative to the current society.  The Institute is funded by the Peace Institute in Slovenia, leftist parties and think tanks in Europe.  Anyway, they asked me to present a lecture on the Euro crisis, to coincide with their enterprising launch of a new Slovenian translation of Marx’s Capital Volume 1.
The subject of the lecture could not have been more apt, because tiny Slovenia, a nation of 2 million people wedged along the Alps, between Italy to the west and Austria to the north, is the only Balkan (ex-Yugoslav) country to be in the Eurozone.  Slovenia has been relatively more prosperous than the other Balkan states and avoided the internecine wars that took place between Croatia, Serbia, Bosnia and Kosovo after the collapse of the ‘communist ‘ Yugoslav federation.  It entered the EU and the Eurozone with great hopes of going forward.  Then the global economic crisis erupted from 2007 onwards. Slovenia seemed to avoid the worst for a while.  But now it has been hit with tremendous damage.  The economy is in a deep recession that began in 2011.  The response of all the political parties has been austerity – under the direction of the EU institutions.  That has been a disaster and eventually Slovenians had had enough.  Last November there were huge demonstrations demanding an end to austerity and a plague on all the political leaders.  This heightened when it was found that both the leaders of the centre-right and centre-left appeared have been involved in corruption scandals.

The Slovenian economic crisis is very similar to that of Ireland.  Slovenia’s state-owned banks had been engaged in massive loans to Slovenian companies, mainly in construction and real estate, stimulating a huge commercial property boom that came crashing down when the global economic slump began.  And just as in Ireland, it has been found that the politicians were in collusion with builders and developers to promote a crazy credit boom, taking a slice of the action for their troubles.
For a while this was covered up, but with unpaid loans now reaching 20% of all lending, the banks are close to bust.  A bailout of the banks is now on the agenda and Slovenia needs at least €5bn by the summer to do it to avoid collapse. Of course, the EU and IMF came up with the usual ‘Irish solution’, which was to hive off all the bad debts into a ‘bad bank’  which the taxpayer must ‘own’, while the cleansed banks are given funds to recapitalise, with the aim of selling them off to foreigners or others as soon as possible.  The Slovenian government will then be left with a public sector debt that will have risen from 23%of GDP in 2008 to 70% by 2017, a massive burden on taxpaying Slovenians.
slovenia debt
And the level of debt built up in the credit boom has destroyed the ability of the banks to provide more credit and companies funds for new investment.  Non-residential capital investment has fallen by nearly 6% of GDP since 2007, as the Slovenian capitalist sector went on strike or bust.  That drop is second only to Ireland in the Eurozone.  The depression is mega-sized for such a small country.
slovenia investment
Since  the protests began, various coalition governments have come and gone.  As I delivered my lecture, a new left-leaning coalition was being endorsed with a female premier, Alenka Bratusek, who is supposedly an ‘expert on finance’.  The new coalition is now faced with finding the money to bail out the banks or going into an EU-IMF ‘Troika ‘ programme as now Cyprus will shortly.  Bratusek says she can deliver economic growth and fiscal austerity at the same time – if so, that will be a first in this euro crisis.  Of course her aim is not really to relieve the burden of Slovenians, but as she says, but to “reassure financial markets” with a program of “three key things: overhaul of the banks; consolidation of public finances in a way that not hurt growth (!); and better management of state assets (does this mean privatisation?)”.

And the Euro crisis continues elsewhere.  As I write, the EU leaders have just decided on a Troika bailout programme for Cyprus, where the banks have been driven to the wall through acting as a conduit for Russian oligarchs’  ‘hot money’ flows.  Cyprus’ economic boom prior to the crisis was based entirely on providing a safe haven for illicit Russian funds, laundering them so they could then be sent back into Russia ‘clean’.  Cyprus attracted $119.7bn of Russian “investment” in 2011 while itself transferring $129.9bn to Russia the same year, equivalent to more than five times the island’s annual output, according to Global Financial Integrity, a US-based money laundering watchdog. Raymond Baker, GFI’s director, said the amounts reflected “round-tripping” of illicit funds exported from Russia to companies based in Cyprus. The funds then flowed back as legitimate investment.
CYPRUS
“I don’t think Cyprus has cleaned up its act. It’s still a centre for disguised entities and for money of suspect origin,” Mr Baker said. “I think the amount of legitimate Russian money coming into Cyprus would be minuscule.”    Cypriot banks used these deposits to invest all over the place: in Greek assets (!) and in property all over Europe.  Now these assets are worthless and they are bust and yet they must meet their obligations to the Russian depositors.  The EU leaders were divided about what to do: they did not want to bail out Russian mafia, but they did not want to set a precedent by reneging on bank debts in case this was used by anti-austerity movements, as in Slovenia, to do the same.  Under pressure from the IMF, the EU leaders have decided that the Russian depositors must take a 10% ‘haircut’ on their deposits, so that of the €17bn needed, only €10bn will now come from the Troika.  Even so, that is a huge burden for Cypriots, equivalent to 40% of annual GDP.  This will be agreed to by Cyprus which has just elected a centre-right president pledged to do so, after throwing out a ‘Communist’ president who was also imposing austerity.

And so it goes on.  Italy is politically paralysed and cannot yet form a government because nobody wants to grasp the nettle of imposing more austerity on an electorate that voted by a large majority against it.  And in Greece, the right-wing coalition government twists and turns with the Troika about how to meet the fiscal targets without imposing even more severe measures that could break up the coalition and engender new elections that could return an anti-Troika leftist party to power.  The government is being asked to sack 150,000 public servants over the next three years, putting all of them on 40% pay right now, along with lots of other measures designed to squeeze yet further the population which has already lost 30% of real incomes.  A deal will be reached with the hope of the government that Greeks will just continue to bear the burden until the Greek economy starts to recover.

But with the Eurozone still in recession this year, even France is getting into trouble.  The French official GDP target for this year was 0.8% but this has now been lowered to +0.2-0.3%. This compares to +0.1% EC forecast. In 2012 growth was zero.   The French budget deficit is seen officially at -3.7% of GDP this year from -4.6% in 2012 (both French government and the EC).   This failure will increase the stresses between Germany and France over meeting EU long-term fiscal targets to get deficits and debt down.  All the bailout countries are getting ‘more time’ to meet their targets.  But without growth, it cannot be done.
And that is what my lecture dealt with: why this is so difficult for the EU leaders to achieve.  The title of the lecture was The euro crisis is a crisis of capitalism. I could have added “and not a crisis of the euro”. In other words, even if  the euro was to collapse and EMU states returned to running their own monetary and currency policies, the crisis would not go away and may even be worse.  That’s because the euro crisis is the product of the failure of the capitalist mode of production globally.  It has had the worst impact on the weaker capitalist economists like Greece, Portugal or Slovenia, but it has hit all.
In my view, that is the point that must be remembered.  The crisis is only partly a result of the policies of austerity being pursued, not only by the EU institutions, but also by states outside the Eurozone like the UK.  If that is right, then alternative Keynesian policies of fiscal stimulus and/or devaluation where possible,will do little to end the slump and will still make households suffer income losses.
Austerity means a loss of jobs and services and thus income.  Keynesian policies will mean a loss of real income through higher prices, a falling currency and eventually rising interest rates.  Take Iceland, a country outside the EU, let alone the Eurozone.  Devaluation, or Keynesian-style ‘beggar-thy-neighbour policies have still meant a 40% decline in average real incomes in dollar terms and nearly 20% in krona terms since 2007.
Picture1
The Euro crisis is product of the slump in global capitalism and the subsequent failure to recover is the same.  Profitability in most capitalist economies is still well below the peak of 2007 (the US is the only exception) and for economies like Italy and Slovenia it is still heading downwards.
Picture10
In the lecture, I correlated profitability with growth since the trough of the Great Recession (graph below).  The trend line is positively sloped.  Estonia and Ireland have seen the biggest recovery in profitability (through austerity and cutting wages and living standards for the population, along with massive emigration of the unemployed).  As a result, they have had the best GDP recoveries – such as they are.  Where the recovery in profitability has been weak or non-existent, real GDP has contracted the most since 2009.
Picture11
The correlation between profitability and growth is much better than between government spending and growth.  Countries where government spending to GDP has increased since 2009 (i.e. Keynesian-style stimulus) like Japan and Slovenia (until now) have not grown at all (see graph below), while there are many countries that applied austerity and reduced government spending to GDP after 2009 and they have achieved some growth.  There is no real correlation between growth and austerity (the trend line is almost flat), whatever Keynesian multipliers might indicate (see my post, The smugness multiplier, http://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2012/10/14/the-smugness-multiplier/).
Picture12
And the build-up of debt, not just for banks, but also for the non-financial capitalist sector is exerting downward pressure on the ability of capitalist economies to recover quickly, even after cutting jobs, closing down businesses and ending investment to reduce the cost of capital.  The more the growth in private sector debt before the crisis, the smaller the recovery has been.  The IMF graph below shows how the level of private debt has held down the recovery.  Balance sheet stress is heavier on the weaker EMU states and the financial centres of the UK and the US.
Picture5
Of course, there are special features involved in the euro crisis.  Capitalism is a combined but uneven process of development.  It is combined in the sense of extending the division of labour and economies of scale and involving the law of value in all sectors, as in ‘globalisation’.  But that expansion is uneven and unequal by its very mode as the stronger seek to gain market share over the weaker.  Yet the Euro project aimed at integrating all European capitalist economies into one unit to compete with the US and Asia in world capitalism.  But one policy on inflation, one short-term interest rates and one currency for all is not enough to overcome the centrifugal forces of capitalist uneven development, especially when growth for all stops and there is a slump.

The aim from 1999 with the Eurozone was that the weaker economies would converge with the stronger in GDP per capita, fiscal and external imbalances.  But instead, as the IMF explained in a recent paper (http://blog-imfdirect.imf.org/2013/02/15/europe-toward-a-more-perfect-union/): “During the years that followed the euro’s introduction, financial integration proceeded rapidly and markets and governments hailed it as a sign of success. The widespread belief was that it would benefit both south and north—capital was finally able to flow to where it would best be used and foster real convergence. But in fact, a lasting convergence in productivity did not materialize across the European Union. Instead, a competitiveness divide emerged. As the financial crisis gripped the euro area in 2010, these and other problems came to the fore…. In fact, there has been little absolute real convergence in the euro area. Those euro area countries that had low per capita incomes in 1999 did not have the highest per capita growth rate”.  The graph below rises up from left to right, instead of being flat.

Picture1
As I show in the lecture, the global slump has dramatically increased the divergent forces within the euro, threatening to break it apart.  The fragmentation of capital flows between the strong and weak Eurozone states has exploded.  The capitalist sector of the richer economies like Germany have stopped lending directly to the weaker capitalist sectors in Greece and Slovenia etc.  As a result, in order to maintain a single currency for all, the official monetary authority, the ECB and the national central banks have had to provide the loans instead.  The Eurosystem’s ‘Target 2′ settlement figures between the national central banks reveals the huge divergence within the Eurozone, although in recent months there has been some reversal back towards convergence.
Picture13
Those who wish the preserve the Euro project like the EU Commission, the majority of EU politicians and most capitalist corporations, recognise that the only way to do so is extend the process towards more integration.  That means a ‘banking union’ so that all the banks in the Eurozone are subject to control by the Euro institutions like the ECB and not national government regulators.  And, above all, by the establishment of a full ‘fiscal union’, so that taxes and spending are controlled by Eurozone institutions and deficits in one EMU state are automatically met by transfers from surplus states.  That is the nature of a federated state like Canada,  the US or Australia. These transfers reach 28% of US GDP compared to the controlled and conditional transfers under EU budgets and bailouts of less than 10% of one state’s GDP.
Picture14
The Eurozone does not have such a fiscal union.  Instead, after much kicking and screaming, the Germans and the EU agreed to set up some fiscal transfer funds, the EFSF and now the ESM.  But these are not automatic fiscal union transfers; they are contingent on meeting fiscal targets in a Troika program and national governments can still set their own budgets.  So there is growing opposition in Germany to shelling out cash for what they see as wayward countries who cannot get their public finances in order.

The IMF summed up the challenge for European capitalism in 2013: “2012 was a year of balancing on the edges of cliffs and precipices for Europe. 2013 needs to be a year of climbing mountains—doing the long and hard work of restoring competitiveness across economies to restore growth and making steady progress on completing the architecture of the monetary union.”

But can it be done?  Is there time and will?  Yes, austerity could eventually deliver the required reductions in budget deficits and debt.  But already there have been years of austerity and very little progress has been achieved in meeting these targets and, more important, in reducing the imbalances within the Eurozone on labour costs or external trade to make the weaker more ‘competitive’.  That could take many more years.  Can the people of Greece, Portugal, Spain, Italy, Cyprus, Slovenia and Ireland endure more years of austerity, creating a whole ‘lost generation’ of unemployed young people, as has already happened in Greece and will happen in Spain, Italy, Portugal and Slovenia?
The electorate is losing patience and is angry as the election turnout and vote in Italy shows and the events in Slovenia.  The EU leaders and strategists of capital need economic growth to  return quickly or further political explosions are likely.  And yet, given the current level of profitability, that may take too long before, perhaps, the world economy drops into another slump.  Then all bets are off on the survival of the euro.

My lecture is on You tube at http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=IaWHNaSRzmY&feature=youtu.be
A lot of people fell asleep.

No comments: