The Triumph of Injustice: how the rich dodge taxes and how to make them pay
is a new book by the inequality experts, Daniel Zucman and Emmanuel
Saez. It’s a searing indictment of American tax system, which, far from
reducing the rising inequality of income and wealth in the US, actually
drives it higher. The authors argue that “even as they became
fabulously wealthy, the rich have seen their taxes collapse to levels
last seen in the 1920s. Meanwhile working-class Americans have been
asked to pay more.” Saez and Zucman show that the super-rich in America actually pay a lower tax rate than everybody else.
On their special website, Tax Justice Now,
they present a wealth of data on the impact of taxation on the
redistribution of income and wealth in the US. There is one staggering
fact: for the first time in over century, The 400 American billionaires
pay lower tax rates than their secretaries; something that billionaire
investor Warren Buffet once jokingly suggested. His joke is confirmed as fact.
Even as they became fabulously wealthy, the ultra-rich have seen
their taxes collapse to levels last seen in the 1920s. Meanwhile,
working-class Americans have been asked to pay more.
Considering all taxes paid at all levels of governments in 2018, the authors find that: “Contrary
to widely held view, US tax system is not progressive. The effective
rate of tax takes into account all forms of taxation on the individual
(income taxes, corporate tax, capital income taxes etc). On that measure
for the top 400 income holders(billionaires) the effective tax rate is
23% while it is 25-30% for working and middle classes. America’s tax
system is now technically ‘regressive’ and is “a new engine for
increasing inequality.”
Why do the poor pay more as a share of their income? There are very
regressive sales taxes: the US has a ‘poor man’s VAT’ not only on goods
and services, but also through higher payroll taxes. And the rich pay
less because income from capital (property and financial assets) is
hardly taxed: corporation tax is low, and there are low rates on
dividends and capital gains. Indeed, US federal corporate tax revenue
almost halved in just one year (2018) with the Trump tax cuts.
Since 2010, it is mandatory to have health insurance in the US but it
is mostly done through employers. The cost is about $13,000 per
covered worker, irrespective of income. So health insurance premiums are
like a huge poll tax administered by employers on behalf of government,
with mandatory payments to private insurers. These insurance premiums
are very regressive.
For the bottom 50% of income earners, average pre-tax income
has stagnated since 1980, at $18,500 per adult. Out of this stagnating
income, a rising share goes to paying taxes and health insurance. In
contrast, at the top, there are booming pre-tax incomes and falling
taxes. Thus inequality of income and wealth rises.
Saez and Zucman argue that there are three main drivers of declining
progressivity: the collapse in capital taxation; allowing tax avoidance
loopholes and outright evasion and; globalization with tax havens and
competition to reduce taxes for foreign investment.
Everywhere, governments are competing to cut taxes for corporations:
the global corporate tax rate has halved since 1980s. The rich
incorporate and retain earnings within their firms and so can save tax
free. They only get taxed when they spend, unlike the rest of us.
The Panama papers revealed the extent of international tax avoidance and evasion. And Zucman’s previous book showed that $7.6 trillion in assets were being held in offshore tax havens,
equivalent to 8% of all financial assets in the world. In the past
five years, the amount of wealth in tax havens has increased over 25%.
There has never been as much money held offshore as there is today. In
2014, the LuxLeaks investigation revealed that multinationals paid
almost no tax in Europe, thanks to their subsidiaries in Luxembourg. In
the US, Americans can set up an ‘offshore company’ in Delaware or other
states like Nevada – they don’t even need to go to Panama.
Nick Shaxson, in his devastating book, Treasure Islands, tax havens and the men who stole the world,
exposed the workings of all these global tax avoidance schemes for the
big corporations and how governments connive in it or allow it. Britain
is already, on some measures, the biggest player in the global tax
haven game. A spider’s web of satellite havens, from the Cayman Islands
and the British Virgin Islands to Jersey, captures wealth from around
the world, polishes it and feeds it to the City of London. The British
Overseas Territories like the British Virgin Islands or Jersey operate
for these purposes and it’s the main source of revenue for these
islands.
A new report from Transparency International, provides the latest evidence of the devastation Britain’s offshore spider’s web causes globally. It tots up £325bn of funds “diverted by rigged procurement, bribery, embezzlement and the unlawful acquisition of state assets”,
from more than 100 countries – mostly in Africa, the former Soviet
Union, Latin America and Asia. The financial criminals include a kingpin
of a multibillion-pound scam to loot Malaysia, and a jailed former
Moldovan prime minister. “Peppered throughout most major cases of bribery, embezzlement and rigged procurement,” says Transparency International, “you will find a UK nexus.”
Saez and Zucman propose to end these iniquities by stopping corporate
tax evasion and tax competition and taxing extreme wealth, while
funding health care and education through progressive income taxation.
Corporate taxation should be on country-by-country profits. For example,
if Apple pays 2% on the profits it books in Ireland, US would collect
the missing 23% from the overall 25% tax rate. If Nestle pays 2% tax
globally but makes 30% of its sales in the US, US would collect 30% of
the 25% US tax rate. If there were an international agreement on a 25%
corporate minimum tax as a pre-condition for further trade
liberalization, then taxes would be at the heart of future trade deals.
The infamous tax havens in countries and islands would be closed down.
But the main proposal to reverse rising inequality of wealth and
income advocated by the authors is a wealth tax. Saez and Zucman
estimate that with a 10% wealth tax above $1 billion, US wealth
inequality can return to its 1980 level. This would also generate
revenue to pay for health and education services. For example, the
wealth tax proposal of Democrat candidate Elizabeth Warren starting at
2% above $50m of wealth to 10% for billionaires would raise 1% of GDP
and would eventually “abolish billionaires gradually”. If there was a 90% top rate, it would “abolish billionaires now”.
The authors also propose a tax on all national income of 6% enough to
fund health care for all. It would mean a big tax cut for the bottom
90%, allowing the abolition of all sales taxes and Trump tariffs.
Consumption taxes would have no role in this ‘optimal tax’.
At a conference organised by the Peterson Institute,
a mainstream think-tank, former Clinton Treasury secretary and
Keynesian guru, Larry Summers attacked the wealth tax proposals. In
particular, Summers argued that Saez and Zucman’s data exaggerated the
regressive nature of the American system because they only looked at
taxation and did not include transfers (social welfare benefits).
Summers reckons: “government policy has become more redistributional if, as is proper, you include benefit.” On
their website, Saez and Zucman dealt with issue of social transfers.
They found that, even after transfers, below average households
benefited little from redistribution. “Since it can be hard to know who benefits from certain forms of government spending (e.g., defense spending)”.
Summers then denied that wealth inequality was an important measure for redistribution. What if we had a “super effective social insurance against retirement, disability & health expenses?”
Then average households would not save so much and would spend their
assets. So the measure of wealth inequality would rise although people
were actually better off! But whether inequality would fall as the
result of a ‘super effective social insurance’ is debatable. And anyway
we don’t have such a system and wealth inequality is very high now.
Summers does not answer the basic question: why is inequality so high in
the US? At least, Saez and Zucman attempt to do so, blaming it on
regressive taxation and tax havens.
Summers’ most excruciating argument against a wealth tax was that “forcing
the wealthy to spend could boomerang. If the wealth tax had been in
place a century ago, we would have had more anti-semitism from Henry
Ford and a smaller Ford Foundation today.” He implies that a
wealth tax would force billionaires to put more money into tax-avoiding
‘foundations’ that could be used to promote nasty right-wing policies
and attitudes like Henry Ford’s foundation in the 1930s. So you see a
wealth tax could generate more fascism from the rich!
Summers had to withdraw that implication. But his conclusion stems
from the assumption that billionaire foundations and charities are the
best way to redistribute wealth, namely at the whim of a rich individual
rather than through government social distribution. Surely, the rich
should pay taxes and everybody should get free public education and
health, and get rid of private schools and hospitals funded by
billionaire donations.
Summers is on stronger ground when he argued that a wealth tax won’t stop the rich controlling the political system: “there
is a very real problem, but the wealth tax will not be remotely
effective in addressing it. It costs $5 million a year at maximum to be a
a central player in either political party. This will be easily
affordable for the rich even with a wealth tax. Very few of the problems
today involve personal contributions of the wealthy. They instead
involve corporate contributions or large groups: e.g., the NRA, the
insurance industry, sugar producers”. Summers went on: “Saez
was unable to provide even a single example of a specific instance of
excessive political power that the wealth tax would address.”
And this is right. The real control of American society is through
the big corporations and their lobbyists; wealthy individual
billionaires play a minor role in that. It is the concentration of
capital at the top through the grip of a few hundred corporations in the
US and globally that is at the essence of power, control and wealth. A
wealth tax on billionaires will help state revenues and reduce
inequalities to some extent. But the power of capital would not really
be dented.
Of course, Summers was not making this point to propose taking over
big capital, but the opposite: to reject a wealth tax on the rich. But
it does expose the weakness of Saez and Zucman’s policy proposals. They
only deal with redistributing income and wealth after the event. But
rising wealth and income inequality are not due to regressive taxation
in the main, but to the structure of investment, production and income
in the capitalist economy, namely the exploitation of labour by capital.
Indeed, rising inequality in the US and in all the major economies
only kicked in from the 1980s onwards when public sector spending on
health prevention and care and on education was cut back
(neoliberalism); all to reverse the low levels of profitability for capital reached globally in the early 1980s.
But inequality of wealth and income existed even in ‘the golden age’ of
the 1950s and 1960s. It was lower mainly because of the strength of
the labour movement, high investment in productive sectors as opposed to
finance and real estate – and also higher taxation.
The reason for rising inequality from the 1980s was a rise in income
going to capital in the form of profits, rent and interest and not due
to the more skilled labour getting higher income than the less skilled.
And this rising capital-income ratio was driven mainly by inherited
wealth. ‘From rags to riches’ is not the story of capitalist wealth: it
is more ‘From father to son’ or ‘From husband to widow’.
This is what Thomas Piketty showed in his book, Capital in the 21st century.
But because he conflated capital into wealth by including
non-productive assets like housing, stocks and bonds in his measure, he
lost sight of how wealth is created and appropriated, as Marx shows with
his law of value: namely through exploitation. As a result, Piketty
(and his colleagues Saez and Zucman) have policy prescriptions for a
better world that are confined to progressive taxation and a global
wealth tax to ‘correct’ capitalist inequality.
And yet Piketty et al recognise that it is utopian to expect the
wealthy (who control governments) to agree to a reduction in their own
wealth. They do not suggest another way to achieve a reduction in
inequality: namely, to raise wage income share through labour struggles
and to free trade unions from the shackles of labour legislation.
And they do not propose more radical policies to take over the banks
and large companies, stop the payment of grotesque salaries and bonuses
to top executives and end the risk-taking scams that have brought
economies to their knees. For them, the replacement of the capitalist
mode of production is not necessary, only a redistribution of the wealth
and income already accrued by capital. Abolish the billionaires by
taxation, not by expropriation.
No comments:
Post a Comment