by Michael Roberts
Apparently Hilary Clinton, the Democratic dynasty front- runner
for the US presidency in 2016 is worried about rising inequality of
income and wealth in America. She has recently consulted Joseph
Stiglitz, Nobel prize winner in economics, and author of now two books
on the issue of inequality.
However, don’t get your hopes up too high that a US president might
take action on the extremes of wealth and poverty in America. Among the
top ten contributors to her campaign are JPMorgan Chase, Goldman Sachs,
CitiGroup and Morgan Stanley. As secretary of state under Obama, she
pressured governments to change policies and sign deals that would
benefit US corporations like General Electric, Exxon Mobil, Microsoft,
and Boeing. Clinton served on WaltMarts board of directors from 1986 to
1992 and the law firm she worked for, Rose Law Firm, represented the
corporation. During her three trips to India as secretary of state, she
tried to convince the government to reverse its law aimed at keeping out
big-box retailers like WalMart.
So anything that Stiglitz might have said will not gain any traction
if Clinton becomes president in 2017. But it shows that inequality is
still THE issue in the minds of the ‘liberal left’ and among mainstream
‘liberal’ economists. Both Stiglitz and Tony Atkinson have new books out
on the subject, while the OECD has a new report out arguing that rising
inequality is damaging economic recovery (http://www.oecd.org/social/reducing-gender-gaps-and-poor-job-quality-essential-to-tackle-growing-inequality.htm).
The OECD sifts through 30 years of data from its predominantly rich
member countries and finds that, when the Gini coefficient, a popular
measure of inequality (a Gini of 0 means everyone has exactly the same
income; a Gini of 1 means one person gets all the income) goes up,
growth declines. But is that because inequality hurts growth, or vice
versa?
The OECD uses a statistical test to conclude it’s the former. The
OECD finds that higher inequality has a significant impact on relative
educational attainment among different income classes. As inequality
goes up, the poorest 40% of the population get fewer skills and lower
quality education.
The OECD then estimates how much more education the
poor may have had if inequality had not increased and plug that into a
growth model that includes components such as human capital. From this,
the study concludes cumulative economic growth was 4.7 percentage points
lower for the average OECD country between 1990 and 2010 (that’s about
$2,500 for the average American).
So the OECD suggests that rising inequality causes slower growth
because the poor get worse education for better skills at work. This is
the cause that is always brought up by mainstream economics (see my
post, https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2010/04/07/inequality-of-opportunity/).
That rising inequality might be a result of the concentration and
centralisation of capital ownership and the application of neo-liberal
policies to increase the rate of surplus value is ignored.
And yet economic inequality has reached extreme levels. From Ghana to
Germany, Italy to Indonesia, the gap between rich and poor is widening.
In 2013, seven out of 10 people lived in countries where economic
inequality was worse than 30 years ago, and in 2014 Oxfam calculated
that just 85 people owned as much wealth as the poorest half of
humanity. In Even it up: time to end extreme inequality (cr-even-it-up-extreme-inequality-291014-en[1]),
Oxfam reckoned that the gap between rich and poor is growing ever wider
and is undermining poverty eradication. If India stopped inequality
from rising, 90 million more men and women could be lifted out of
extreme poverty by 2019.
Tony Atkinson is the father of modern inequality research (see my post, https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2013/07/14/the-story-of-inequality/),
providing the data and evidence on inequality of incomes in the major
economies well before Emmanuel Saez or economics rock star, Thomas
Piketty (see
http://weeklyworker.co.uk/worker/1013/unpicking-piketty/).
Atkinson’s latest book, Inequality what is to be done aims to look at what should be done to reduce inequality. (http://www.hup.harvard.edu/catalog.php?isbn=9780674504769)
As well as diagnosing the problem of economic inequality (especially
inequality of income)—showing why it matters in advanced societies (“It does matter that some people can buy tickets for space travel when others are queuing for food banks”) and how it has changed over time, Atkinson presents a series of policy proposals for doing something about it.
Rising inequality is not some inexorable long-term process in
capitalism (namely a larger rate of return on wealth over the growth in
national income) as Thomas Piketty has argued. Atkinson reckons rising
inequality is directly the result of neo-liberal policies introduced
from the late 1970s onwards. Cuts in the welfare state probably
accounted for a substantial part of that [rise in the gini inequality
number]. And these could be reversed.
Atkinson makes the valuable point that what matters for inequality is who controls the levers of capital. “In
the old days, the mill owner owned the mill and decided what went on
[there]. Today, you and I own the mill. But who decides what goes on?
It’s not us. That’s the important difference. And it doesn’t really
appear in Piketty’s book, which is actually more about wealth than it is
about capital.”
Yes it is capital not wealth (as Piketty thinks) that matters – but
is Atkinson right to think that the owners of capital have in some way
relinquished control to pension funds? The owners of capital – the
billionaires – still control the means of production (http://www.forbes.com/sites/bruceupbin/2011/10/22/the-147-companies-that-control-everything/)
and make the decisions on wages, bonuses, shareholdings and government
policy on corporate taxes and welfare benefits (see my post, https://thenextrecession.wordpress.com/2015/02/01/growth-inequality-and-davos/ ).
Atkinson seems to accept neoclassical welfare economics, namely that
an economy will run efficiently and that any intervention like
redistribution will make it less efficient, so there’s a trade-off. But
he says this only applies to perfect competition whereas economies are
really dominated by monopolies. “In that less perfect world, it’s not clear that there is any such trade-off.”
But there is no trade-off in the world of perfect competition either
because that is an imaginary construct of mainstream economics.
Atkinson calls for a living wage, guaranteed government employment
for 35 hours, works councils to give people a say in their jobs;
investment in technology for jobs, higher marginal income tax rates (up
to 65%, he says); a wealth and inheritance tax with the revenues to be
used to invest in pensions. All this sounds fine, although it does not
deal with the very issue that Atkinson poses in his book, namely the
control of the levers of capital. So his excellent reforms to reduce
inequality will just bounce off the deaf ears of the likes of Hilary
Clinton.
As I said earlier, Joseph Stiglitz apparently does have the ears of
Clinton – for the moment. Stiglitz has just published his second book on
inequality called The Great Divide, http://books.wwnorton.com/books/detail.aspx?id=4294987343.
In it, he stresses a range of economic and institutional changes
weakening ordinary workers that serve to benefit the wealthiest in
society. For example, the bonuses that Wall Street executives received
in 2014 was roughly twice the total annual earnings of all Americans
working full time at the federal minimum wage. Stiglitz rages at the
callous ignorance of the rich: “I overheard one billionaire — who
had gotten his start in life by inheriting a fortune — discuss with
another the problem of lazy Americans who were trying to free ride on
the rest,” Stiglitz writes. “Soon thereafter, they seamlessly transitioned into a discussion of tax shelters.”
For him, however, reducing inequality does not depend on controlling
the levers of capital but on ‘more democracy’. As Stiglitz notes: “Inequality is a matter not so much of capitalism in the 20th century as of democracy in the 20th century.”
Whereas Piketty believes that extreme inequality is inherent to
capitalism, Stiglitz argues that it’s a function of faulty rules and
regulation. While he admires Marx’s critiques of exploitation and
imperialism, he has little time for his analysis of economics.
Stiglitz’s positions are essentially Keynesian and would have been
viewed as fairly conventional in the pre-Thatcher and pre-Reagan era.
“My argument is that these guys – the bankers and monopoly
corporations – have destroyed capitalism in some sense,” he says. “There
are certain rules which are required to make a market economy work. And
these guys are really undermining these rules. My book is really about
trying to get markets to act like markets. That’s hardly radical, at one
level. But at another level it is radical because the corporations
don’t want markets to look like markets.”
Atkinson’s answer is a radical redistribution of income and wealth
through tax, employment and welfare measures. Stiglitz’s solution is
more regulation of the banks and monopolies by democratic governments.
Don’t hold your breath waiting for a Democratic Clinton to do either or
both.
for more inequality, see my Essays on Inequality
Createspace https://www.createspace.com/5078983
or Kindle version for US:
http://www.amazon.com/dp/B00RES373S
and UK
http://www.amazon.co.uk/s/?field-keywords=Essays%20on%20inequality%20%28Essays%20on%20modern%20economies%20Book%201%29&node=341677031.
No comments:
Post a Comment